This paper was
published by the Georgetown International Environmental Law Review in January
of 2003. A final version of this paper
can be found on Lexis or Westlaw at the following citation:
15 Geo.
Int'l Envtl. L. Rev. 291
Stalemate in the Aral Sea Basin: Will Kyrgyzstan’s New Water Law Bring the Downstream Nations Back to the Multilateral Bargaining Table?
Gregory
E. Heltzer*
I. Introduction.....
II. Causes of the Current State of Affairs in Central Asia.
A. Soviet Policies Still Wreaking Havoc Today......
B. Water Anxiety Grows: The Competition Between Upstream and Downstream Nations.................
C. Major Environmental Concerns: Drawing the World’s Attention.............
D. Upsetting the Balance.................
E. The Regional Structures in Place.....................
F. Major International Efforts and Pressure...............
G. The Rise of the Bilateral Agreement and Weakness of International Accords: Kyrgyzstan Forces the Issue.
III. International Law and Water as an Economic Good.....................
A. A Right to Water?..................
B. International Law and Free Water....................
IV. Kyrgyzstan’s New Law and Its Effect on Regional Discussions.........
A. Kyrgyzstan’s New Law and the Dublin Statement.............
B. Kyrgyzstan’s New Law and Implications for the Contested 1992 Almaty Agreement
C. Kyrgyzstan’s New Law Clarifies Aspects of the 1998 Syr Darya Framework Agreement...........
D. Kyrgyzstan’s Equity Argument.
V. Solving Central Asia’s Water Stalemate..............
A. Reinstitute the Local Fee: When Fees Were Eliminated, Irrigation Became Wasteful..............
1. The Efficient Traditional Method of Irrigation with Strong Local Oversight.............
2. The Inefficient Soviet Style Irrigation Method and the Wastefulness of Free Water...........
3. The Importance of the Fee.............
VI. Conclusion....
VII. Appendix A: Map of Central Asia.
VIII. Appendix B: Timeline of Important Agreements and Events in Central Asia Since the Fracturing of the Soviet Union.......
The fledgling nations of Central Asia – Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, and Uzbekistan – are dependent on the Amu Darya[1] and Syr Darya[2] for their water resources.[3] These rivers[4] act as a “cultural, economic, geographical and political core for Central Asia.”[5] The Amu Darya and the Syr Darya rivers account for ninety percent of the surface water in the Aral Sea Basin (the Basin) and support seventy-five percent of Central Asia’s population (forty-five million people).[6] The Basin covers over 1.8 million square kilometers and is almost entirely composed of the five Central Asian nations.[7]
Historically populated by agrarian societies, the region contains plentiful arable land; however, most of this land is only useful when irrigated.[8] Large-scale irrigation was made a reality during the Soviet reign. Since then, it has decimated the water resources of the Basin in terms of quantity and quality.[9] This stress on water resources is most clearly manifested in the precipitous decline of the Aral Sea itself. During the last forty years, the sea has shrunk to one-third its historical[10] size. The Aral Sea, located at the terminus of the Basin, is fed almost entirely by the Amu Darya and the Syr Darya.[11] Because the rivers struggle to reach the sea, it is easy to conclude that overuse due to irrigation is at the root of the problem.
Over the last several decades, the Soviet Union’s geographical hold, “economic might and political-military power”[12] allowed it to dominate water management in the region. Therefore, for much of the century the Kremlin was the governing body for settling water disputes in the region.[13] The collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991 not only stunned the West, but also provided for an entirely new balance of power in Central Asia (not limited to water disputes). The Central Asian republics, now each its own sovereign nation, have competing use interests for the waters of Central Asia.[14] “None of these states is yet in a position, geographically, politically, economically or militarily, to dictate management policy for the Basin on its own terms;”[15] this makes negotiations an attractive method for resolving disputes.
Despite the power parity in the region, geographic and demographic statistics indicate that some nations have significant claims to future water allocations in the region.[16] These claims should be taken into consideration in any water negotiations. Four nations[17] have primary stakes in the region because their populations are almost entirely dependent on the Basin’s water: Tajikistan is entirely within the Basin; 99% of Uzbekistan is in the Basin; 99% of Turkmenistan’s population and 80% of its land are within the Basin; and 70% of Kyrgyzstan and more than half of its people are in the Basin.[18] Though they have smaller percentages of their populations and landmasses dependent on the Aral Sea Basin, Kazakhstan and Afghanistan also have considerable interest in the region’s water allocations.[19] Looking at the region from a basin perspective, no nation has a larger claim than Uzbekistan, which controls 25% of the Basin’s area and has 50% of the Basin’s population.[20] Understanding these nations’ dependency on the waters of the Basin helps explain the current state of negotiations for water in the region.
The population of the Basin is largely dependent on water because agriculture is the leading economic force.[21] The style of agriculture employed is “heavily dependent on extensive irrigation, requiring the application of huge quantities of water.”[22] This form of irrigation has depleted all surface water in the Basin.[23] Following the demise of the Soviet Union, the principal issue in this arid region has been finding a way to equitably allocate the region’s surface waters. As Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan try to maintain their stranglehold on the region’s water withdrawals,[24] other Basin States are clamoring for an increase in their water share.[25] The tensions associated with managing the region’s water have been steadily increasing, largely because of the upstream water-rich nations’ ability to cut off supply with Soviet-era infrastructure designed to control flow for the region.[26] The cutoffs, used largely in negotiations over future water allocations and payment for infrastructure upkeep and water storage, have sparked acrimonious, and sometimes violent, relations among the nations.[27]
International negotiations over water in the Basin have been active for over a decade, and many multilateral agreements have been reached.[28] However, these agreements[29] do not have adequate enforcement mechanisms[30] and have not held up when the region has experienced a drought or an especially cold winter.[31] More distressing than the failure of these agreements is that the downstream nations, Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan, have changed their political course and now boycott regional negotiations; instead, they favor politically expedient but environmentally negligent bilateral agreements with the upstream nations.[32]
The failure of these multilateral agreements is largely the
result of conflicting water uses by upstream and downstream nations.[33]
For example, Kyrgyzstan, an upstream nation, desires to release water
from its dams throughout the year and especially during the winter to generate
electricity through hydropower to keep its cities lit and warm.[34] However, this use directly conflicts with
the downstream nations’ agricultural use.
The downstream nations want Kyrgyzstan to curb its water release until
the spring and summer growing season. [35]
Bilateral barter agreements between upstream and downstream nations have served to mitigate these competing uses. Since 1994, Kyrgyzstan has been receiving cotton, natural gas, oil, and coal from its downstream neighbors in exchange for holding the majority of the Syr Darya’s water back until the growing season.[36] Meanwhile, on the larger Amu Darya, upstream Tajikistan has been learning from Kyrgyzstan’s example and is also orchestrating barter agreements with downstream users.[37] The downstream nations are essentially compensating the upstream nations for infrastructure upkeep and for curbing the release of water during the winter months so that there will be enough water for lucrative downstream agriculture during the growing season.
Unfortunately, these bilateral agreements are failing as well. Such agreements are generally informal, the terms of the agreements are not released for public examination, and if the agreements are violated they are difficult to enforce. Water released to downstream users can be used as a political tool to force payment for water or the settling of debt owed.[38] The upstream nations justify these political water games because they feel “shortchanged” by the barter agreements and instead want cash for maintaining upstream infrastructure.[39]
Upstream Kyrgyzstan has shaken up the status quo of yearly
bilateral agreements to curb water release during non-growing periods by trying
to turn water into a commodity.[40]
Kyrgyzstan wants to replace barter agreements with cash compensation for
water released to its downstream users, Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan.[41] While this may sound similar to the barter
agreements already in place, charging downstream nations cash for water is
unprecedented in the international community.
Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan have condemned this move, focusing their
attacks on the law passed by the Kyrgyz pParliament,
while ignoring the Kyrgyz explanation for the law.[42]
The law calls for the selling of water as a commodity.[43] Kyrgyzstan desires to sell water at a price
that would extract enough in fees out of its downstream neighbors to pay the
downstream nations’ equitable portion of Kyrgyzstan’s yearly U.S. $25 million dollar infrastructure upkeep bill.[44] Attempting to eliminate the barter
agreements in favor of a fee for water could be a blessing and help the
region’s transitioning economies.
By charging a fee for water rather than bartering for water, Kyrgyzstan encourages efficiency from its downstream users. The resources Kyrgyzstan receives in return for the water are produced at a cheaper cost than the price these resources are assigned in the barter exchanges. Efficient water use would greatly benefit the region’s productivity, environment, stability, and overall health, as access to safer drinking water would probably increase. Furthermore, by forcing payment from downstream users, Kyrgyzstan could bring Uzbekistan, the biggest player in the region, back to the multilateral bargaining table, which would aid the region in determining equitable allocations based upon international water principles. Once an equitable agreement is reached, each nation would own a certain amount of the region’s water, and could then contract away surplus water for a price on a yearly basis. However, until that time, Uzbekistan must negotiate with Kyrgyzstan and pay for its water. Uzbekistan may soon realize it is far cheaper to reach equitable water allocations at the regional level and pay for only part of the water it receives rather than pay for all the water it receives.
This note will analyze the unique problems of water management in Central Asia in the wake of the Soviet collapse. The primary focus is on the possible outcomes of recent politicking over payment for water in the region between upstream and downstream nations. Part II will examine the causes of the current state of water affairs in Central Asia. Part III will analyze international law and discuss whether water can be treated as an economic good. Part IV will examine Kyrgyzstan’s new water law and its effect on regional discussions. Part V will look at possible future outcomes as a result of pursuing water fees in Central Asia.
The Central Asian nations are all ex-republics of the Soviet Union, and the policies of this former global superpower have shaped the issues the region faces today.[45] In the 1920s and 1930s, the Soviets created five republics in Central Asia, substantially redrawing the region’s political boundaries.[46] The creation of the new republics disrupted the region’s natural watershed by dividing the two major watercourses into upstream and downstream regions.[47] The consequences of the division of the republics in this fashion were further exacerbated by two decisions. First, the Soviets constructed massive water storage infrastructure in the upstream republics to provide control mechanisms for the region’s water.[48] Second, the Soviets continued their Tsarist predecessors’ goal of transforming the arid downstream republics into money making agricultural societies[49] whose primary crops were water-intensive cotton and rice.[50] The infrastructure implemented and the agriculture goal for the arid downstream regions forced the republics to be interdependent during the Soviet reign.
As far as managing the water by employing a total
basin approach, the Soviets’ plan was the responsible and proper[51]
method of approaching the issue.
However, the Soviet redrawing of political borders, the construction of
water infrastructure, and Moscow’s fascination with irrigating as many hectares
as possible haves
led to today’s highly political water dispute.
When the Soviet Union disintegrated along the political boundaries it
had created, it gave birth to a water conflict because Moscow was no longer the
sovereign decisionmaker for the region.[52] Today, instead of one nation implementing a
single water policy for the region, five competing nations must negotiate for
water use – the water towers of Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan and the water
dependent nations of Uzbekistan, Kazakhstan, and Turkmenistan.[53]
Because little, if any, surface water currently reaches the Aral Sea (a problem that can only be solved through the implementation of better, more efficient irrigation techniques), the riverine waters in Central Asia are fully allocated.[54] Of the four largest rivers and tributaries in the region, each is shared by at least two nations.[55] More than half of Uzbekistan’s water and ninety-eight percent of Turkmenistan’s water originates in another nation.[56] Seventy-three percent of Aral Sea Basin water is allocated to the three downstream arid states of Kazakhstan, Turkmenistan, and Uzbekistan,[57] while the upstream nations of Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan are only allocated 0.4% and 11% of the Basin’s water respectively, despite providing 80% of Central Asia’s available surface water.[58] This water use scenario triggers a classic struggle between upstream and downstream riparians.
The high water use by downstream nations is not itself a problem. However, when the waters are fully allocated and the upstream, water-controlling nations begin demanding higher allocations because the current scheme is inequitable, strife is sure to follow. The surface water in Central Asia is of high economic significance.[59] Ninety percent of the region’s crops are grown on irrigated land.[60] In Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan, cotton farming is the leading employer and income generator.[61] Forty-four percent of Turkmenistan’s workforce is employed in the cotton industry and over seventy-five percent of Uzbekistan’s revenue is generated through cotton farming.[62] In stark contrast, the upstream nations are not so agriculturally dependent that they require massive amounts of surface water for farming. Instead, these nations depend on water for hydroelectric power.[63] During the Soviet era, these nations did not have to deal with competing water use concerns; free water was provided to the downstream nations and free fossil fuels were provided for heat and electricity to the upstream nations.[64] Because the nations of Central Asia are no longer part of the Soviet economic system, “the promotion of national economic interests and mutually incompatible demands for water” have complicated the politics in the region.[65]
The Aral Sea serves as a constant reminder to the region of the continuing stress placed on water resources there. The disappearance of the Aral Sea is considered “one of the most serious environmental crises in the world.”[66] As the sea recedes, massive amounts of salt and other minerals accumulate on the former sea bottom and mix with the remnants of toxic pesticides and herbicides.[67] The salt, dust, minerals, and chemicals form a toxic brew that often gets caught up in windstorms and covers areas up to 500 kilometers away with the mixture.[68] Not only does the sea bottom degrade the arable land surrounding the sea, it also causes severe respiratory problems for many people.[69] The overuse of the Basin’s surface water has also destroyed the Aral’s fishery, on which so many depended.[70] As the surface waters flowing to the Aral reduced in size, the brackish sea became too salty and polluted for indigenous fish, effectively eliminating 60,000 jobs associated with the fishery.[71] Fallout from the desiccation of the Aral Sea also extends to loss of biodiversity in the river deltas, climate change in the region surrounding the diminished sea, and pollution of groundwater – directly impacting the safety of drinking water in the region.[72]
Compounding the overuse problem in the Aral Sea Basin is population growth.[73] In Uzbekistan alone there are 400,000 new mouths to feed each year.[74] The Central Asian nations grew by 140% between 1959 and 1989 and are projected to increase by another third before 2020.[75] The most phenomenal population increases are occurring in the Ferghana Valley,[76] possibly the most fertile region of Central Asia, whose borders are shared and disputed by three nations: Kyrgyzstan, Uzbekistan, and Tajikistan. Furthermore, over half of the Basin’s population lives in the prime irrigated areas of the Ferghana Valley, Lower Zeravshan, and the Tashkent-Khujand Corridor,[77] demonstrating the connection between farming and intense competition for finite water resources.[78]
The environmental degradation in the Basin is so
dynamic that it has drawn intense international interest to the region.[79] Unfortunately, the international advisors
are more concerned with solving the environmental problems by curtailing water
use and saving the Aral, rather than taking into consideration the desires of
the Basin nations.[80] This international position has upset the
Basin nations, who would rather fully allocate the water to aid their economies
and deal with the environmental costs ex post facto rather than ex
ante.[81] Following the demise of the Soviet Union,
the nations began meeting to allocate the waters of Central Asia and at the behest
of the international community, much lip service was paid to the environmental
problems the region faces.[82] These meetings seemed to have solved the
allocation issues by leaving intact the same water distribution levels as under
Soviet rule,[83] while carving
off a small portion for the Aral Sea. [84] However, the distribution scheme was
seriously flawed because the allocation levels are not equitable for the
upstream states and because the downstream nations have little interest in
helping the Aral Sea if it will hurt their economic interests in irrigated
agriculture.[85]
Unfortunately, leaving the water allocation levels at pre-sovereignty levels is not an equitable solution for the region. Today, the upstream states are responsible for infrastructure upkeep, but receive little benefit in return.[86] Also, under the Soviet economic plan, the upstream republics were receiving fossil fuels for electricity and heat from downstream republics, in exchange for the upstream republics’ controlled release of water during the summer months.[87] This was an even bargain because the upstream republics then had enough heat during the winter so that they did not need to rely on hydroelectric power and release water during the winter. They could instead save the water and release it for the downstream users during the crucial summer growing season. Furthermore, the massive economic gains made in growing cotton from the free upstream water did not benefit the individual republic in which it was grown, but instead went to the Kremlin’s coffers and was used for the good of the region, and nation, as a whole.[88]
When the nations gained sovereignty, the natural resource allocation balance was upset. In 1992, the Almaty Agreement set water allocation amounts at Soviet-era levels.[89] This agreement amounted to an economic windfall for the downstream nations.[90] The new downstream nations’ coffers were being filled with money made from cotton, and they no longer had to provide their fossil fuel resources for free.[91]
Most nations with trans-boundary water resources can see possible water disputes approaching years in advance.[92] These nations then have the requisite foresight to negotiate over water allocation amounts and implement water basin management regimes before the resource becomes too overstressed.[93] The Soviet Union implemented an inequitable regime to maximize arable land in its possession, believing Central Asia to be “a single agricultural region for economic purposes.”[94] Following the collapse of the Soviet Union, the Central Asian nations “were forced to rapidly develop management strategies and assume responsibility”[95] and did not have the luxury of time. The nations began developing their own divergent views on appropriate water use.[96] An inequitable scheme could no longer work because each nation was sovereign; instead, the region required a new and more cooperative allocation system.[97]
Following their independence, each nation claimed equitable shares to water resources in Central Asia. On September 12, 1991, the nations jointly stated “that mutual water resources management would be on a basis for equity and joint benefits.”[98] On the heels of this statement, the nations put together the Almaty Agreement[99] in February 1992. Under this agreement, the nations acknowledged that “only [through] unification and joint coordination of action could the region’s water crisis be effectively managed”[100] and that the region’s waters were “common and integral.”[101] The agreement retained the water allocations put in place by the previous Soviet regime; refrained from commencing projects and activities that would deviate from agreed water shares, including projects that would affect water quality; pledged the free exchange of water basin information; and agreed to carry out projects that would jointly address the desiccation of the Aral Sea.[102]
The Central Asian nations have formed various organizations to oversee the Aral Sea Basin, clearly indicating their desire to negotiate and best manage the region’s water. These organizations include: the Interstate Commission for Water Coordination (ICWC); the Basin water-management authorities (BVOs)[103] – one for the Amu Darya and one for the Syr Darya; the Interstate Council on Problems of the Aral Sea Basin (ICAS); and the International Fund for the Aral Sea (IFAS).[104]
Over the last decade, the ICWC became part of the ICAS, which was then swallowed by a redesigned IFAS in 1997.[105] The goal of combining these organizations was “to reduce duplication of effort, simplify the administrative structure, overcome bureaucratic inertia and revitalize improvement efforts in the Aral Sea Basin.”[106] The new IFAS is led by the head of state of one of the Central Asian nations and rotates every two years.[107] It is composed of the Deputy Prime Ministers of the Central Asian nations that oversee agriculture, water, and the environment.[108] IFAS’s annual contributions now stand at 0.3% of GNP from Uzbekistan, Kazakhstan, and Turkmenistan, and 0.1% from Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan.[109] The integration of these organizations and the continual agreements that these structures churn out – the nations signed as many as three hundred agreements on the Basin between 1991 and 1994[110] – indicate that the countries are well aware of the gravity of the situation.
The organizations in place collectively decide water allocation amounts among the nations, oversee the regulation of surface waters in the Basin, and act as a sounding board for future projects on the watercourses.[111] Most notably, the IFAS provides a forum for continuous dialogue among the nations to settle disputes.[112] It would seem that IFAS is the critical structure for dealing with water disputes in the region and for overseeing the Aral Sea Basin; however, in practice, the organization is weak, with little actual political commitment and minimal financial and legal backing.[113]
Since the collapse of the Soviet Union, international non-governmental organizations and donors have led the charge in promoting peaceful solutions for the management of Aral Sea Basin waters.[114] International pressure to avoid a water conflict in the region is largely responsible for the quick agreement on water allocation reached in 1992. The 1992 pact, which was based on inequitable Soviet-era water allocations, probably avoided a stalemate and has aided the nations transition to sovereign powers. However, by endorsing and giving precedent to the Soviet allocation amounts, the region and the international community have aided the downstream nations in securing water for inefficient irrigation practices.
The World Bank (the Bank) has been the most active player in Central Asia since 1992. The Bank created the Aral Sea Basin Program (ASBP), a project that was scheduled to run for fifteen to twenty years and cost U.S. $250 million.[115] The ASBP has three primary goals: “(1) the rehabilitation and development of the Aral Sea disaster zone; (2) strategic planning and comprehensive management of the water resources of the Amu Darya and Syr Darya; (3) building institutions for planning and implementing the above programs.”[116] The Bank encouraged the formation of the ICAS and IFAS and through these organizations has sought fulfillment of the ASBP’s agenda.[117] The preparatory phase of the program ended in mid-1997, and since then the program has been focused on improving management of the water resources. Specifically, it seeks to determine ways to deal with water quality concerns by developing low cost conservation measures at the local, farm-specific level.[118] Other aspects of the program involve strengthening water-sharing among the nations, educating the public to effect a behavioral change in the way Central Asian nations use water, improving dam and reservoir management, and, most importantly, monitoring water quality and quantity exchanged between the nations’ watercourses.[119] Without accurate numbers on water quality and quantity, it is impossible to reach an equitable solution.[120] Monitoring is the “precondition of more effective and accepted interstate water management/sharing agreements.”[121]
Another key program in the region is the United States Agency for International Development (USAID). This program focuses on the Syr Darya Basin, specifically the Toktogul dam and reservoir. This storage facility, built by the Soviets and currently owned by Kyrgyzstan, controls downstream water release for Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan.[122] The primary disagreement over the dam involves the competing water uses of irrigation and hydropower and trying to reach an equitable agreement to avoid a conflict.[123] In 1998, the Syr Darya Basin countries signed a framework agreement to aid the nations in settling future disputes.[124] USAID then formed a small follow-up project to help implement the agreement reached, but this has met with much stronger resistance, due primarily to Uzbekistan’s desire to solve water issues with more direct bilateral agreements rather than through multilateral roundtables.[125]
The regional allocation agreements and frameworks implemented during the last decade are very helpful in assessing the state of affairs on the water issue throughout the region, but have had very little actual effect when water resources have become stressed or when water is used as a pawn in much broader economic negotiations among nations. When dialogue at the roundtable fails, bilateral swap or barter agreements[126] have picked up the slack and steered the region through crisis on an increasing basis.[127] Over the last decade, the bilateral agreements have primarily involved only upstream Kyrgyzstan and its downstream neighbors on the Syr Darya, because the Syr Darya contains less water than the Amu Darya.[128] The scarcer the resource, the faster nations must allocate it properly or suffer. Furthermore, the other upstream nation, Tajikistan, was involved in a civil war, which dramatically hindered its ability to negotiate with downstream nations over water allocation.[129]
As far back as 1994, upstream Kyrgyzstan and downstream Uzbekistan made an informal barter agreement, “under which Uzbekistan agreed to provide Kyrgyzstan with winter heat and electricity in exchange for water during the growing season.”[130] This informal arrangement was secured just two years after the Almaty agreement allegedly set the water allocation amounts in the region at Soviet-era levels. However, following independence, two key aspects of the Soviet-era allocations changed: (1) Uzbekistan was now gaining all of the proceeds from their cotton[131] plantations, not the Kremlin; and (2) Kyrgyzstan was no longer receiving subsidies of fuel and electricity to keep the nation operational during the cold winter months.[132] It was not until these two issues became apparent that downstream Uzbekistan backed off its right to water free of charge – Uzbekistan simply could not justify the exorbitant amount of water it used without paying for infrastructure upkeep in some fashion.[133] The argument can therefore be made that water in the region has never been free, save for a short period just following the nations’ independence from the Soviet Union.[134]
The notion that water in the region is not free is the key to understanding the issues facing Central Asia and water allocation. If the issue was that Kyrgyzstan was trying to charge Uzbekistan money for potable drinking water, the equities[135] would be much different and the notion of charging money for water would then be unpalatable. Instead, it seems there is more than enough water in the Central Asian nations to support their populations and economies.[136] However, there is not enough water to satisfy all the uses and plans that these nations’ governments have.[137] The primary explanation for the lack of water for all these uses is inefficient distribution and use stemming from the nations’ water-intensive irrigation techniques.[138] It has been estimated that “[c]rops in Central Asia may receive between four and six times the amount of water they require.”[139] By forcing the downstream nations to value the water and invest in better delivery systems, the entire region would benefit.
The leaders of downstream Uzbekistan, Kazakhstan, and Turkmenistan[140] have stated their opposition to Kyrgyzstan’s desire to charge cash for water they receive.[141] This issue will take on extraordinary importance if, as is likely, Tajikistan follows suit and also decides to charge cash for water.[142] The opposing nations’ leaders only argument against the proposal is that it contradicts “international norms and rules,”[143] an inaccurate statement. The “international norms” on which these downstream nations are basing their opposition have largely been set by the influential writings of Stephen McCaffrey and Peter Gleick, who contend that there may be a right to water for vital human needs.[144] These writers have articulately and passionately argued that international law suggests that water must be made available to those who need it for drinking and sanitation purposes.[145] The writers note that little attention in international law has been given to whether there is a right to water[146] and that water rights have been mentioned explicitly only once, in the Convention of the Rights of the Child.[147] However, they contend that a right so important as access to safe drinking water can be inferred from existing covenants and declarations on human rights agreed to by members of the United Nations.[148]
But by basing the counterargument of the downstream nations on this notion of a possible general human right to water, the leaders are conflating two issues. The “international norms” of which they speak would only apply to situations where there is not enough water to provide potable drinking water. This is not the problem in Central Asia. In Central Asia there is plenty of water available to drink and for sanitation purposes, but the way in which the downstream governments use that water is creating the water crisis. By charging a fee for water, Kyrgyzstan would be aiding these nations in maintaining their future water supply, and forcing them to re-evaluate the wasteful way in which they use water.[149]
The downstream nations have a good argument for establishing a right under McCaffrey’s and Gleick’s scholarly analyses to receive enough water, free of charge, from upstream watercourse nations for the basic human needs of its population.[150] However, under this theory, the downstream nations are not necessarily entitled to all the water they have historically received without a fee because a large percentage of the water they have historically received is in excess of what these nations’ populations require for basic human needs. Therefore, even if there is a right to water for basic human needs, the downstream nations must still compensate the upstream nations for infrastructure upkeep for the water received in excess of basic human needs.
Upstream Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan, as well as international parties, have sought multilateral negotiations on equitable water management in the Basin, but these attempts have largely failed because of boycotts by the downstream nations.[151] Any Basin-wide agreement would require downstream nations to contribute funds to maintain infrastructure that largely benefits downstream interests. By boycotting regional negotiations on Basin water management, the downstream nations are forcing Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan to threaten cut-offs unless they are paid. Therefore, the move by Kyrgyzstan (with Tajikistan likely to follow suit) to charge a fee for water is a product of downstream nations’ own intractableness. While the downstream nations do have strong equitable interests in Basin water allocations negotiated at the multilateral level, they are effectively ceding that right by refusing to negotiate on a regional basis.
The downstream nations’ position is further weakened when looking at their rhetoric. These nations continually reiterate that they will not pay for water.[152] However, these nations would not be paying for water; they would be paying for infrastructure upkeep and compensating Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan for lost hydropower use. By phrasing their opposition based upon “international norms,” the downstream nations are muddying the waters and confusing issues to put political pressure on the upstream nations. This tactic seems to have had some effect, as the newspaper headlines coming from the region are alarmist in nature and always refer to the destabilizing effect of water on the region.[153]
Modern international law suggests that water, unlike fossil
fuels, is a “free” resource and should be given openly in equitable amounts to
downstream users. The preeminent
framework for analyzing watercourse disputes, the United Nations Convention
on the Law of the Non-Navigational Uses of International Watercourses, was
developed in 1997.[154] It has yet to be ratified, but arguably
represents the current consensus among the world’s nations on international
water law. The Convention does
not explicitly state that water should not be sold to downstream users, but
does make provisions for a balancing of equitable uses with “vital human
needs.”[155] By declaring that “vital human needs” play a
role in determining allocation amounts between nations, it suggests that water
is a resource that must in some circumstances be permitted to pass through free
of any constraints – including payment.
Analyzing the Convention more broadly, it seems that water must
be allocated in “equitable and reasonable” terms as discussed in Article 5,
while taking into consideration that every nation along a watercourse has a
stake in the water: “[E]every watercourse State is entitled to
participate in the negotiation of and to become a party to a watercourse
agreement that applies to the entire international watercourse . . . .….”[156] Taking Article 4 of the Convention,
“Parties to water course agreement,” and Article 6, “Factors relevant to
equitable and reasonable utilization” together, it can be surmised that the
intended purpose of the Convention would be to determine water
entitlements for each nation along a watercourse. The word “entitlement” means that each watercourse nation would
be allocated a certain amount of water based upon the Article 6 factors.[157] If the watercourse nations are entitled to a
certain amount of water based upon equitable and reasonable factors, then an
upstream nation could not charge downstream nations for water that exceeds the
upstream nation’s quota. Stated more
succinctly, to charge another nation for water, the upstream nation would have
to give up some portion of its entitlement for a fee.
While the water itself is considered free, the Convention
does acknowledge that all users should pay for aiding infrastructure upkeep,
albeit infrastructure in one’s own territory.[158] Article 26, Section 1 of the Convention
says, “[w]atercourse states shall, within their respective territories, employ
their best efforts to maintain and protect installations, facilities and other
works related to an international watercourse.”[159] This statement seems to suggest that nations
are responsible for upkeep of infrastructure within their territory. However, the Convention assumes that
each nation has its own infrastructure to maintain. While the downstream nations do have their own water
infrastructure, this infrastructure is for agriculture – a domestic
purpose. The infrastructure for
which that Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan seek
help with is for downstream international
purposes. Furthermore, since
independence, the upstream nations have been receiving bartered payment for
storing water, curbing water use, and maintaining water infrastructure. For the above reasons, it seems that Article
26 of the Convention has little application in the Basin.
On June 29, 2001 Kyrgyzstan’s parliament published a law on “the inter-governmental use of water resources, dams and other water-related installations.”[160] President Askar Akayev signed the law into effect on July 23, 2001.[161] This law is modeled on the 1992 Dublin Statement on Water and Sustainable Development[162] and states that “water has an economic value in all its competing uses and should be recognized as an economic good.”[163] These words are exactly the same as those used in Principle Number 4 of the Dublin Statement.[164]
The media and international response to this new law has been shrill.[165] Most articles postulate that if members of the region adhere to the agreement, then Kyrgyzstan, and Tajikistan, if it follows Kyrgyzstan’s lead, will force payments from their downstream neighbors for water.[166] This is in contrast to previous arrangements where Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan only received barter payments for maintenance of the water infrastructure, curbing release of water during the non-growing season, and storing water.[167] However, these articles have failed to analyze the accompanying language of Principle Number 4 and the statements of Kyrgyzstan’s Prime Minister.
The accompanying language of Principle Number 4 in the Dublin
Statement recognizes “the basic right of all human beings to have access to
clean water . . . …at
an affordable price . . . . .…Managing
water as an economic good is an important way of achieving efficient and
equitable use, and of encouraging conservation and protection of water
resources.”[168] Inherent in these words is the notion that
Kyrgyzstan could never charge the full value of water because that would
prevent all human beings from having access to that water. Rather, Kyrgyzstan is attempting to change
the form of payment for its water storage, infrastructure upkeep, and loss of
hydropower generation during the winter months from the barter arrangements
already in place to a fee structure.
The statements of Kyrgyz Prime Minister Bakiev also support the notion that the new Kyrgyz water law is intended only to force cash payment for installation maintenance, water storage, and the loss of hydropower generation during the winter months. Prime Minister Bakiev has intimated that the recently passed legislation was put in effect because Kyrgyzstan uses less than twenty-five percent of the water in Kyrgyz reservoirs and “our neighbors don’t pay anything for the water they get. We’re paying for it.”[169] The Prime Minister’s statements suggest that the impetus for the law was that his nation feels “short-changed” by the bilateral barter agreements.[170] The hope is that the new water law will more equitably compensate Kyrgyzstan for the control services it provides to its downstream neighbors.
The new law approved by the Kyrgyzstan’s parliament and signed by President Akayev caps years of discussion on how to treat Kyrgyzstan’s water and, more importantly, suggests a new official stance by Kyrgyzstan that the Almaty Agreement has no force.[171] The 1992 Almaty Agreement, which codified Soviet-era water allocations for the five fledgling nations, has frustrated international water negotiations in the region for years.[172] Language in that treaty defined water resources in the region as “common and integral,” thereby frustrating attempts to make water into an international commodity.[173] Over the last decade, despite entering into barter agreements for water storing, Uzbekistan has tried to rely on the language from this accord in all subsequent negotiations, claiming that all signatories of the agreement must abide by it.[174] However, the Kyrgyz Parliament, led by Mr. Tudarkun Usubaliev, a revered politician and leader of the republic from 1961-1985, has debated the validity of the agreement from the start.[175] Usubaliev and his fellow detractors have claimed that the “agreement was never ratified by Parliament, and that [the] agreement violates the terms in Kyrgyzstan’s own Law on Water,” and that the Minister of Water Economy who signed the agreement had no authority to do so.[176] By signing a law that transforms water into a commodity that can be sold at the international level, the legislature and executive branches of Kyrgyzstan are agreeing that the 1992 Almaty Agreement has no force. While the Almaty Agreement has had no actual force for years, it has been the basis for Uzbekistan’s and Turkmenistan’s boycotts of recent multilateral negotiations. If Kyrgyzstan can force a change in the type of payment it receives from its downstream neighbors, these nations may rethink their boycott of multilateral negotiations and return to the bargaining table to more equitably allocate the Basin’s water according to the upstream nations’ desires.
The 1998 Framework Agreement[177] among the governments of Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan, and Kyrgyzstan[178] is a framework agreement that is the closest the region has come to achieving a more equitable multilateral accord since the inequitable Basin-wide 1992 Almaty Agreement. The 1998 Framework Agreement acknowledges the competing-use issues between upstream and downstream nations, noting that any curbing of water release by an upstream nation for downstream concerns should be met with equivalent “compensations for energy losses.”[179] Infrastructure upkeep costs, also known as operation and maintenance costs, are to be paid for by the nation that owns the facilities.[180] The agreement also codifies past bilateral barter agreements, explicitly stating that the purpose of Kazakhstan’s or Uzbekistan’s payment by coal, gas, electricity, fuel oil, or labor and services is for water storage by Kyrgyzstan.[181] Implicit in the notion of Kyrgyzstan being paid for storing water is the idea that the water stored, though on Kyrgyzstan’s land, is not owned by Kyrgyzstan. This suggests that Kyrgyzstan, Uzbekistan, and Kazakhstan have agreed in principle that each nation is entitled to an equitable share of water. In an accompanying agreement, the nations outlined what these equitable shares were.[182] However, the shares outlined have not been adhered to in the years following the agreement, largely because of drought and failure of the downstream nations to adequately compensate Kyrgyzstan for water storage and lost hydroelectricity production during the winter months.[183]
The 1998 Framework Agreement, therefore, explicitly provides that downstream nations must compensate Kyrgyzstan for two things: (1) water storage – curbing of non-growing season water release; and (2) potential energy supplies lost because of water storing.[184] The agreement explicitly states that operation and maintenance costs must be paid for by the nation that owns the infrastructure.[185] However, if this is true, what determines the cost of water storage? The cost of water storage must necessarily be the operation and maintenance of infrastructure if compensation for energy not generated is treated as a separate source of compensation, which is how the Framework Agreement treats it. Thus, Kyrgyzstan’s new water law builds on aspects of the 1998 Framework Agreement by attempting to flesh out what Kyrgyzstan should be compensated for.
Since 1997, Kyrgyzstan has begun to vocalize its
desire to treat water as “any other valuable commodity – something that can be
bought and sold, for a real market price.”[186] The equity argument in favor of selling
water as a commodity is surprisingly strong.
The Director of Kyrgyzstan’s Institute of Hydroenergy has noted that “of
the 50,000 million cubic meters of water that Kyrgyzstan’s lakes and reservoirs
collect each year, only 12,000 million cubic meters remain in the country.”[187] While Uzbekistan irrigates 1.6 million
hectares of fields each summer, Kyrgyzstan is limited by the water it releases
to Uzbekistan to only 0.5 million irrigated hectares.[188] Furthermore, because of Uzbekistan’s high
water use, water that could have been held back for hydropower generation
during the cold winter months was already released during the summer, thus
limiting Kyrgyzstan’s autumn and winter hydropower generation .[189] This practice of being unable to generate
electricity during the hard winter months is very costly as Kyrgyzstan is then
forced to import electricity from Uzbekistan.
Even more surprising is that “Uzbekistan makes no contribution to
[Kyrgyzstan’s] upkeep of dams and mountain weather stations which monitor water
levels.”[190] It therefore seems logical that to untangle
this mess and to achieve maximum efficiency in poverty-stricken nations, a
price should be placed on every resource.
Bartering may solve disputes today, but for true economic freedom and
best use of the resources involved, cash payment is the only way to move
forward.
Since the nascent days of independence, Kyrgyzstan has pressed its downstream neighbors for payment on water provided from its reservoirs so that it could maintain its crumbling water infrastructure, which is vital to downstream interests. Following Kyrgyzstan’s lead, Tajikistan has also recently become involved in downstream barter agreements to aid it in infrastructure upkeep.[191] Since 1994, Uzbekistan has provided natural gas, coal, and cotton to Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan to compensate the nations for money spent on infrastructure upkeep, water storage, and the curbing of water release during the non-growing season.[192] Recently, Kazakhstan has provided coal and power engineering equipment to aid Kyrgyzstan in maintaining its infrastructure.[193] However, the value of these resources is often far less than the cost of upkeep of infrastructure and usually is just enough to keep the upstream nations warm and operational during the winter.[194] This inequity chafes the upstream nations.
The current bilateral barter agreements are seriously
flawed in other respects as well. The
barter agreements allow upstream nations to hold any downstream nation hostage
on a political whim. In the past, Uzbekistan,
downstream from Kyrgyzstan,
but upstream from other Basin nations, has cut off Kazakhstan’s water for
non-payment of debt.[195] Kazakhstan retaliated by halting
international telephone calls routed through Kazakhstan to and from Uzbekistan,
forcing callers to use a far more expensive network.[196] In another example, Kyrgyzstan has frozen
the release of Kazakhstan’s water until the debt Kyrgyzstan owed Kazakhstan was
relieved.[197] Uzbekistan has interrupted natural gas
deliveries to Kyrgyzstan on numerous occasions as a pre-emptive strike,[198]
and Kyrgyzstan has threatened to sell water to China if Uzbekistan does not pay
for its water use.[199] Troops have been massed on borders in the
region in response to water politics,[200]
and there have even been extortion disputes at the local level, with one farmer
refusing to release his upstream water until the downstream farmer ceded to
some sort of demand.[201] Furthermore, all of these disagreements tend
to occur just before or during the growing season, seriously hampering the
cultivation of lucrative crops and resulting in massive agricultural losses.[202]
The upstream nations have become very frustrated with
bilateral barter agreements, with Kyrgyzstan being the most vocal on the
subject and Tajikistan following suit.[203] Since 1997 there has been talk of charging
cash for the water provided to downstream users, and in 2001 Kyrgyzstan
officially started moving towards this end with the signing of the new water
law.[204] The Kyrgyz pParliament
approved the law that defines water as a commodity and,
one month later, Kyrgyzstan announced that it was preparing a method of
charging downstream users for water.[205] Kazakhstan and Uzbekistan have both spoken
out against the new law saying that it “contradicts the international norms.”[206]
However, the goal of this movement is not to create a market for water and charge the full price for water, but to get compensation for infrastructure upkeep, water storage, and loss of hydropower generation during the winter months.[207] The payment that Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan desire can more accurately be described as a fee to maintain the upstream nations’ future ability to provide water for their downstream neighbors. Furthermore, Kazakhstan’s and Uzbekistan’s rhetoric on the subject is puzzling considering that they have already been involved in barter deals to provide the same ends.
Kyrgyzstan’s water fee plan, which will also probably be implemented by Tajikistan, is not new to the region and should be supported by the international community until the downstream nations return to the multilateral bargaining table. The 1998 USAID-led agreement on the Syr Darya Basin states that developing a pricing mechanism based on a single tariff is a primary future goal of the region.[208] If Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan are able to secure fee payment from the downstream nations rather than the current barter agreements, it will force the downstream nations to quantify the cost of water they are receiving. The logical outgrowth of the new payment to the upstream nations would be for the downstream countries to place the new fee burden on their water users, forcing them to become more efficient with water and to institute water metering at the local level.
The Soviets did a great disservice to Central Asia when they rejected traditional irrigation practices that had been used for centuries and replaced those practices with more modern centralized approaches that led to extreme waste and inefficiency.[209]
If traditional forms of irrigated agriculture were still practiced in Central Asia, the surface waters of the region would not be so depleted. “The traditional system of irrigated agriculture in the Aral Sea Basin was essentially preserved until the mid-1920s.”[210] The traditional irrigation method “had been developed over thousands of years and had survived through wars, social collapse, natural catastrophes and the Tsarist conquest of the region.”[211] Individual farmers and their extended families oversaw nearly all of the irrigated land locally.[212] These micro-managed farms were generally no bigger than two or three hectares and the fields that comprised each farm were heavily regulated and had permanent walls lined with trees breaking up the land into plots approximately 0.5 hectares in area.[213] Animal waste was the primary fertilizer, which emphasizes that those who lived there were accustomed to using all resources to their maximum efficiency.[214]
The traditionally irrigated farms were a sustainable method of agriculture in the region. The small size of the fields allowed the farmers to prevent unequal distribution of water and run-off.[215] The trees lining the borders of each plot served as a fuel source during the winter, prevented waterlogging, and lowered wind speeds to prevent erosion and evaporation from the soil.[216] Despite having poor delivery canals, which is where most of the inefficiencies were concentrated, water was on the whole used very efficiently with the traditional irrigation method.[217]
The traditional administrative regime for water
disbursement that was in place when Soviet authorities assumed control of water
distribution in Central Asia fostered strong oversight to maintain efficient
use of water.[218] Those who used water for irrigation were not
only taxed to maintain the canals and water distribution system, but were
expected to help build and maintain the local systems themselves.[219] Farmers had “obligatory annual work to clean
canals of sediments, repair dams and other facilities and deal with any other
maintenance or construction issues that needed attention.”[220] Furthermore, “Islamic law saw water as
social property,” and farmers were encouraged to cooperate
locally in maintaining their irrigation systems.[221] The arid environment also contributed to the
general mindset in the region that water should be used carefully. The traditional method of irrigation was
sustainable, and while what
has replaced it is not.
The Soviets could have used the best aspects of the traditional irrigation techniques and introduced more modern Western technologies to improve the efficiency of the small farms in Central Asia. Instead, the Soviets viewed the traditional irrigation method as “primitive, backward and inefficient, as well as exploitative and oppressive of the peasantry.”[222] The Soviets instituted state control of irrigation and agriculture,[223] thus eliminating the fees on the actual farmers.[224] They increased the plot size of farms, and sought to get as many acres irrigated as possible.[225] But with the increase in plot sizes and inattention to efficient distribution techniques, the Soviets ended up using all of the water available in the region and wasting most of it.[226] The Amu Darya and Syr Darya water supplies “were approaching exhaustion,”[227] fields were waterlogged and salinized, and yield was declining.[228] Even worse, the new administrative methods “killed off the art of irrigation learnt over centuries. When water [was] provided it [was] done so only in huge quantities that harm[ed] both vegetation and people.”[229] By removing ownership of the farmland from local families and making these farmers and peasants employees of the state, apathy towards farming led to irresponsibility that has become “rooted in people’s attitudes for decades.”[230]
The modernization of Central Asia’s agricultural techniques is not the sole reason for the current water strife in the region. More accurately, the issue is one of inefficiency and waste that has accompanied the modernization. By removing land ownership and subsidizing water projects, the Soviets removed the type of local monitoring necessary to prevent land from becoming damaged and water from being wasted. Without the individual farmers being constantly conscious of water use, because of fees associated with its misuse, waste at the local level became rampant. Furthermore, even with the demise of the Soviet Union this waste has yet to be alleviated because water use continues to be subsidized[231] in the agrarian societies of Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan, two nations that used more than seventy-two percent of Aral Sea Basin water in 1995.[232]
One of the best methods for efficiently allocating a scarce resource is through price.[233] By charging an amount of money for water that does not force a farm into bankruptcy or even significantly hurt the farm’s bottom line, the Central Asian nations can encourage efficiency in irrigation practices. Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan have experimented with irrigation fees over the last several years.[234] The water fees collected in these nations have not been enough to cover infrastructure upkeep costs.[235] However, detractors who point to this “failure” of water fees are missing the point. The long-term goal of water pricing may ultimately be to cover the cost of operation and maintenance or even future water projects, but in the short- to mid-term the goal is to use water more efficiently so that there is more available for all competing uses. If Kyrgyzstan is successful in charging downstream nations for water, it is very likely that fees will be passed on to the local level for water use. If the local farmers need to limit their water use to cut down on the fees assessed, then irrigation practices will be influenced. The primary obstacle to imposing a local fee on farmers is a water metering system.[236] Currently, water usage tends to be “calculated by multiplying the area of each crop by the water usage norm for each crop raised (i.e., what should be used, not what is used) and summing the results.”[237] The inefficiencies of such a practice suggest that there is little actual monitoring at the local level. Instituting metering at the local level should be at the forefront of any international effort for water conservation in Central Asia because this is the most direct method of improving water use efficiency. Only when a farmer can be shown the amount of water used with accurate data, in comparison with other more efficient and productive farms, will irrigation abuses wane.[238]
The Aral Sea Basin is flush with water. However, the amount of water available from year to year fluctuates substantially due to drought cycles.[239] During these droughts the Basin nations feel the strain on their agriculturally dependent economic systems, and during years of plenty the water cannot be properly stored to prepare for these droughts because of a crumbling water infrastructure. A multilateral agreement that equitably allocates surface water is needed in the Central Asian region because it is just the first step in addressing the water management issues this region faces. Only after allocation levels are set can these nations proceed to address other issues like joint infrastructure upkeep, creating a regional authority with control over water distribution, and better monitoring and fee implementation at the local level. Currently, Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan are boycotting multilateral discussions on allocating the Basin’s water and are keeping this process from moving forward. Kyrgyzstan’s move towards requiring cash payments for water, rather than continuing with inefficient barter exchanges, may force these nations back to the multilateral bargaining table, especially if Tajikistan follows Kyrgyzstan’s lead. In a region struggling for stability, this may be the best avenue toward equitable allocation of water resources.
Year |
Event |
Description |
1991 |
Soviet Union Disintegrates |
The Central Asian republics are splintered into
five sovereign nations: Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan, and
Turkmenistan. |
1991 (Sept.12) |
Joint Statement |
The newly independent Central Asian nations
jointly state “that mutual water resources management would be on a basis for
equity and joint benefits.” |
1992 |
Almaty Agreement |
Sets water allocation amounts at Soviet-era
levels, calls region’s water “common and integral,” and places a hold on new
water infrastructure projects. The
agreement currently has no force and is characterized as inequitable by the
upstream nations. Kyrgyzstan also
asserts that it has never ratified the agreement and therefore it is of no
significance. |
1992 |
Dublin Statement on Water
and Sustainable Development |
Principle 4 of the Statement: “water has an
economic value in all its competing uses and should be recognized as an
economic good.” This becomes the
basis for Kyrgyzstan’s new water law. |
1994 |
Bilateral Agreements |
Bilateral barter agreements between Kyrgyzstan and
Uzbekistan commence. Tajikistan follows suit later in the 1990s. |
1997 |
UN Convention |
United Nations Convention on the Law of the
Non-Navigational Uses of International Watercourses is adopted. |
1997 |
World Bank: Aral Sea Basin
Program (ASBP) |
Project ends its preparatory phase and begins
focusing on improving water management at the local level. |
1997 |
Cash for Water |
Kyrgyzstan first begins advocating a “cash for
water” scenario. |
1998 |
USAID and the Syr Darya
river |
The Syr Darya nations, Kyrgyzstan, Uzbekistan,
Kazakhstan, and Tajikistan, put together a framework agreement for allocating
the water of this river. Agreement
codifies past bilateral barter agreements and acknowledges that upstream
nations should be compensated for the water services they provide. Implementation of the agreement has been
stonewalled by Uzbekistan. |
2001 (July) |
Kyrgyzstan’s new water law |
President Akayev signs the law into effect after
it passed through Parliament on June 29, 2001. |
* J.D. Candidate 2003, Georgetown University Law Center; A.B. Environmental Studies, Dartmouth College 1999. I would like to thank Professor Edith Brown Weiss for convincing me to pursue publication of this note and the editors and staff of the Georgetown International Environmental Law Review for their hard work.
[1]. The Amu Darya originates primarily in Tajikistan and forms the Uzbek-Afghan border before turning north and crossing over between Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan several times before ending in the Aral Sea. Bruce Pannier, Central Asia: Water Becomes a Political Issue, RFE/RL Newsline 1, at http://www.rferl.org/nca/features/2000/08/F.RU.000803122739.html (Aug. 3, 2000).
[2]. The Syr Darya forms in Kyrgyzstan and runs through Tajikistan, Uzbekistan, and Kazakhstan to the Aral Sea. Id.
[3]. Stuart Horsman, Water in Central Asia: Regional Cooperation or Conflict?, in Central Asian Security 69, 70 (Roy Allison & Lena Jonson eds., 2001).
[4]. See Appendix A.
[5]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 70.
[6]. Id.
[7]. Philip Micklin, Managing Water in Central Asia 1 (Edmund Herzig ed., 2000). Iran has minimal territory in the Aral Sea Basin and provides no meaningful trans-boundary source of water for the other nations. Therefore, it has little stake in the Aral Sea Basin’s surface waters. Id. at 3; see also Horsman, supra note 3, at 78. Afghanistan contributes eight percent of the Basin’s surface flows and nearly a third of Afghanistan’s land mass is in the Aral Sea Basin, including 7.9 million people; however, Afghanistan has been at war for decades and is currently in the midst of installing a new government with Western aid while trying to retain control over various warlords. Micklin, supra, at 3; see also Horsman, supra note 3, at 78.
While Afghanistan has a claim to some of the Aral Sea Basin’s surface waters, the nation is currently not in a position to use those waters and must first establish peace within its borders before negotiating with its neighbors. The Soviet Union has also dominated water politics in the region for decades. Its policies largely ignored Iranian and Afghani concerns, and management of the Basin was primarily a domestic concern. Since the fall of the Soviet Union, there is now no major global player in the region. Afghanistan’s isolationism with the Taliban government during the 1990s, and the current chaos the country is in, make including this nation a difficult task. Furthermore, Iran’s contribution to the Basin has not changed. Therefore, Iran and Afghanistan will not be the focus of this study.
[8]. Glenn E. Curtis, Introduction to Fed. Research Div., Library of Cong., Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan: Country Studies xl (Glenn E. Curtis ed., 1997).
[9]. Id.
[10]. In this context, the word “historical” means the stable size from 1910 (when monitoring began) to 1960 (when large scale withdrawals of water increased). Studies have shown that the Aral Sea’s size changed tremendously throughout the millennia due to climate changes, geographic changes, and river flow changes. Philip P. Micklin, Desiccation of the Aral Sea: A Water Management Disaster in the Soviet Union, Sci., Sept. 2, 1988, at 1170.
[11]. Laurence Boisson de Chazournes, Elements of a Legal Strategy for Managing International Watercourses: The Aral Sea Basin, in International Watercourses: Enhancing Cooperation and Managing Conflict, World Bank Technical Paper No. 414, 65 n.1 (Laurence Boisson de Chazournes & Salman M.A. Salman eds., 1998).
[12]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 1.
[13]. Id.; see also Horsman, supra note 3, at 72.
[14]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 72.
[15]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 3.
[16]. Id.
[17]. Tajikistan, Uzbekistan, Turkmenistan, and Kyrgyzstan.
[18]. Micklin,
supra note 7, at 3.
[19]. Id.
[20]. Id.
[21]. See Horsman, supra note 3, at 71; Micklin, supra note 7, at 5.
[22]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 5.
[23]. See
generally id.
[24]. These two nations account for 72% of the water withdrawn from the Basin each year. Id. at 9.
[25]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 74-75.
[26]. See id. at 75.
[27]. See id. at 75-77.
[28]. Id. at 72.
[29]. See Appendix B.
[30]. See Horsman, supra note 3, at 73.
[31]. See Bruce Pannier, Kyrgyzstan: Prime Minister Faces Power and Border Problems, RFE/RL Newsline, (Mar. 19, 2001), at http://www.rferl.org/nca/features/2001/03/19032001115718.asp (discussing effects of cold winters) [hereinafter Prime Minister Faces Problems]; see also Pannier, supra note 1 (discussing effects of drought on the region); see also Arslan Koichiev, Water Games Could Leave Central Asia High and Dry This Summer, EurasiaNet Environment (Mar. 19, 2001) (discussing the effects of drought on Central Asia), at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav031901.shtml.
[32]. Bea Hogan, Decreased Water Flow Threatens Cotton Crop, Peace in Region, EurasiaNet Environment (Aug. 2, 2000), available at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav080200.shtml.
[33]. See E. A. Chait, Water Politics of Syr Darya Basin, Central Asia: Question of State Interests, at http://www.iwra.siu.edu/pdf/Chait.pdf (last visited Oct. 23, 2002).
[34]. Id.; Prime Minister Faces Problems, supra note 31.
[35]. This is not exactly true. The downstream nations do desire some water to be released during the winter, prior to the growing season, so that farmers can flush their fields of accumulated salts, a byproduct of the wasteful flood irrigation technique. H.L. Carlisle, Hydropolitics in Post-Soviet Central Asia: International Environmental Institutions and Water Resource Control, (Columbia Int’l Affairs Online, Working Paper, Mar. 6, 1998), at http://www.ciaonet.org/wps/ria01/igcc29ad.html.
[36]. Koichiev, supra note 31.
[37]. See Central Asia: Water and Conflict, ICG Asia Report, No. 34, 10 May 30, 2002, at http://www.intl-crisis-group.org/projects/asia/centralasia/reports/A400668_30052002.pdf.
[38]. Koichiev, supra note 31.
[39]. Beatrice Hogan, Kyrgyz Authorities Concerned About Retaliatory Raids Against Central Asian Reservoirs, EurasiaNet Environment (Oct. 16, 2001), at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav101601.shtml; see also A Daily Review of News from Kyrgyzstan, RFE/RL Kyrgyz News (Naryn Idinov trans.), Aug. 8, 2001, at http://www.eurasianet.org/resource/kyrgyzstan/hypermail/200108/0019.html [hereinafter A Daily Review].
[40]. Jeremy Bransten, Kyrgyzstan/Uzbekistan: The Politics of Water, RFE/RL Newsline, Oct. 14, 1997, at http://www.rferl.org/nca/features/1997/10/F.RU.971014134935.html.
[41]. Id.
[42]. A Daily Review, supra note 39; Alisher Khamidov, Water Continues To Be Source of Tension in Central Asia, EurasiaNet Environment (Oct. 23, 2001), at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav102301.shtml.
[43]. Khamidov, supra note 42.
[44]. A Daily Review, supra note 39.
[45]. See generally Horsman, supra note 3.
[46]. Bea Hogan, Central Asian States Wrangle Over Water, EurasiaNet Environment (Apr. 5, 2000), available at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav040500.shtml.
[47]. Id.; Chait, supra note 33.
[48]. Chait, supra note 33.
[49]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 70.
[50]. Chait, supra note 33.
[51]. Except maybe for the Aral Sea’s health, which will be discussed infra.
[52]. See Horsman, supra note 3, at 72.
[53]. Id.
[54]. Even if an allocation agreement among the nations was achieved, this water would still be fully allocated. There are simply too many economic interests to allow the water to reach the Aral Sea before being used. In my view, the Aral Sea will only be able to recuperate if the water efficiency of agriculture is improved. Until then, the Aral Sea remains in jeopardy.
[55]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 70.
[56]. Id. at 71-72.
[57]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 44. Uzbekistan receives 38%, Turkmenistan receives 26%, and Kazakhstan 8% under the agreements for 1996-1997. The Aral Sea is supposed to receive 16.4% of the Basin’s water, but this has not happened. See Micklin, supra note 7, at 45.
[58]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 44-45; Stuart Horsman, Water in Central Asia: Regional Cooperation or Conflict?, in Central Asian Security 64, 71 (Roy Allison & Lena Jonson eds., 2001).
[59]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 71.
[60]. Id.
[61]. Id.
[62]. Id.
[63]. Stefan Klötzli, The Water and Soil Crisis in Central Asia – a Source for Future Conflicts?, ENCOP Occasional Paper No. 11, Ch. 4 (1994), at http://www.fsk.ethz.ch/encop/11/en11-con.htm.
[64]. Bransten, supra note 40.
[65]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 71.
[66]. Curtis, supra note 8, at xl.
[67]. Micklin, supra note 10, at 1173.
[68]. Id. at 1174.
[69]. Id. at 1175-76; David Kohn, Man-Made Drought Wreaks Havoc in Karakalpakstan, EurasiaNet Environment (Feb. 26, 2001), at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav022601.shtml; Alanna Shaikh, While Urgench Drinks, The Uzbek Desert Approaches, EurasiaNet Environment (July 9, 2001), at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav070901.shtml.
[70]. Micklin, supra note 10, at 1174.
[71]. Up to 100,000 jobs may have been eliminated depending on with whom you speak. Id.; see also Kohn, supra note 69.
[72]. See generally Micklin, supra note 10, at 1175-76.
[73]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 71.
[74]. Kohn, supra note 69 (quoting unidentified researcher).
[75]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 71.
[76]. Id.
[77]. These three farming areas comprise less than 20% of the landmass of Central Asia but house over 50% of its population. Id.
[78]. Id. at 71-72.
[79]. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 75.
[80]. Daphne Biliouri, The International Response to the Aral Sea, EurasiaNet Environment (Jan. 12, 2000), at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav010600.shtml (“For the Aral Sea to return, [the 5 central Asian republics] will have to stop all irrigation for 10 years. People will die upstream just to refill the sea. What is the value of that?”).
[81]. Id.
[82]. Curtis, supra note 8, at xl.
[83]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 72.
[84]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 43-48.
[85]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 71.
[86]. The downstream nations are supposed to provide support for infrastructure, but little money is actually transferred between the nations. See Prime Minister Faces Problems, supra note 31.
[87]. Bransten, supra note 40; Horsman, supra note 3, at 71.
[88]. Bransten, supra note 40.
[89]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 72.
[90]. See Bransten, supra note 40.
[91]. See id.
[92]. See Horsman, supra note 3, at 72.
[93]. For example, negotiations over the Nile River waters began in the early 1900s, continued after the region’s nations gained independence in the 1950s, and still continue today to ensure that water does not become an overstressed resource in the region. See generally Christina M. Carroll, Note, Past and Future Legal Framework of the Nile River Basin, 12 Geo. Int’l Envtl. L. Rev. 269, 272-83 (1999) (outlining all of the agreements concerning the surface waters of the Nile River basin during the twentieth century).
[94]. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 68.
[95]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 72.
[96]. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 68.
[97]. Id.
[98]. Id.
[99]. Also known as the “Agreement on Cooperating in the Management and Utilization and Protection of Water Resources in Interstate Sources.” Id.
[100]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 72 (quoting the Almaty Agreement).
[101]. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 68.
[102]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 72; Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 68.
[103]. The BVOs were established for each river in 1986, well before independence from the Soviet Union. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 68; Micklin, supra note 7, at 44.
[104]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 72-73.
[105]. Id.
[106]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 48.
[107]. Id.
[108]. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 69.
[109]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 73.
[110]. Id.
[111]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 43-48.
[112]. Horsman, supra note 3, at 73.
[113]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 52.
[114]. See generally Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 65-70.
[115]. The estimated cost has been increased to U.S. $470 million dollars. Micklin, supra note 7, at 48-49.
[116]. Id. at 49, 66.
[117]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 49.
[118]. Id. at 49-50.
[119]. Id. at 50.
[120]. Id. The watercourses’ quantity and quality were monitored under Soviet rule, but the observation stations established during the Soviet regime are “rapidly deteriorating.” Id.
[121]. Id.
[122]. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 72.
[123]. Interestingly, the Soviet Union saw this problem coming and was set to build a series of dams for hydroelectric power for the Kyrgyz Republic just above this reservoir. The understanding was that with the construction of these dams, all water in the reservoir, though in the Kyrgyz Republic, was now the property of the downstream republics. Unfortunately, the upstream dams were never built, resulting in a stalemate over the competing uses of this dam and reservoir. Had the dams been built, this dispute would have been deflated. See Chait, supra note 33 at 3.
[124]. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 72.
[125]. See Bea Hogan, Decreased Water Flow Threatens Cotton Crop, Peace in Region, EurasiaNet Environment (Aug. 2, 2000), available at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav080200.shtml.
[126]. Barter agreements exchange one resource for another, e.g., Kyrgyzstan trades water to Uzbekistan in exchange for some amount of coal, natural gas, and cotton.
[127]. Hogan, supra note 46.
[128]. See Pannier, supra note 1.
[129]. Chait, supra note 33, at FN1.
[130]. Bransten, supra note 40.
[131]. Often referred to in the region as “white gold.” Id.
[132]. Id.
[133]. See id.
[134]. In fact, the Soviets were scheduled to begin instituting charges for irrigated water in 1991, but then the nation fractured. Micklin, supra note 7, at 59.
[135]. The change in equities here would wholly concern basic human rights.
[136]. See H.L. Carlisle, Hydropolitics in Post-Soviet Central Asia: International Environmental Institutions and Water Resource Control, Institute on Global Conflict and Cooperation, (Mar. 1998), at http://www.ciaonet.org/wps/ria01/igcc29ad.html (stating that 90% of water in the region is used for irrigation and that only 20-30% of that water ultimately reaches the crops for which it was intended); see also Stuart Horsman, Environmental Security in Central Asia, The Royal Institute of International Affairs, Briefing Paper New Series No. 17, at 3 n.10 (Jan. 2001) (noting that even the most stressed areas of Central Asia have more water per person than the UN recommends for an effective industrial state).
[137]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 68.
[138]. Id.; Carlisle, supra note 136; Micklin, supra note 10, at 1170-76.
[139]. Carlisle, supra note 136.
[140]. This assumes that Turkmenistan is still following Uzbekistan’s lead, which it has tended to do in the past, most notably in boycotting multilateral negotiations for water allocation. See Decreased Water Flow, supra note 32.
[141]. A Daily Review, supra note 39; Khamidov, supra note 42.
[142]. See Central Asia: Water and Conflict, ICG Asia Report, No. 34, at 17, (May 30, 2002), at http://www.intl-crisis-group.org/projects/asia/centralasia/reports/A400668_30052002.pdf.
[143]. A Daily Review, supra note 39; Khamidov, supra note 42.
[144]. Stephen C. McCaffrey, A Human Right to Water: Domestic and International Implications, 5 Geo. Int’l Envtl. L. Rev. 1, 22 (1992); see generally Peter Gleick, The Human Right to Water, 1(5) Water Policy 487-503 (1999), available at http://www.pacinst.org/gleickrw.pdf.
[145]. Gleick, supra note 144, at 487-503; McCaffrey, supra note 144, at 1, 14.
[146]. McCaffrey, supra note 144, at 1.
[147]. Gleick supra note 144, at 487-503.
[148]. McCaffrey, supra note 144, at 9-10; Gleick, supra note 144, at 487-503.
[149]. Presumably, the less water that is withdrawn by downstream users, the less they would have to pay because they would be less reliant on Kyrgyzstan’s reservoirs.
[150]. McCaffrey, supra note 144, at 18-23.
[151]. See Decreased Water Flow, supra note 32.
[152]. See also A Daily Review, supra note 39.
[153]. Decreased Water Flow, supra note 32 (entitled: “Decreased Water Flow Threatens Cotton Crop, Peace in Region); Koichiev, supra note 31 (entitled: “Water Games Could Leave Central Asia High and Dry this Summer).
[154]. United Nations Convention on the Law of the Non-Navigational Uses of International Watercourses, U.N. GAOR, 51st Sess., Supp. No. 49, U.N. Doc. A/Res/51/229 (1997), available at http://daccess-ods.un.org/doc/UNDOC/GEN/N97/772/93/PDF/N9777293.pdf, also available at http://www.mtnforum.org/resources/library/uncln97a.htm (last visited Oct. 23, 2002) [hereinafter Convention].
[155]. Id. art. 10(2).
[156]. Id. art. 4(1).
[157]. Id. art. 6(1) (the Article 6 factors include: natural environment factors affecting the watercourse; social and economic needs of the watercourse states; population dependent on the water; effects of the use of the watercourse by one nation on another nation; existing and potential uses of the watercourse; conservation uses; alternatives available to a planned or existing use).
[158]. Generally, this can be alternatively achieved by creating independent multinational basin management organizations that each member nation helps fund through annual fees. This basin management organization is then responsible for upkeep of infrastructure and control mechanisms along the river. This method has been widely discussed as a possible solution to the Nile River negotiations and represents the current situation in the Basin. However, because the member nations of the Basin do not fully fund the organization, its ability to carry out this duty is stunted.
[159]. Id. art. 26(1).
[160]. Rene Cagnat, The Tide Turns in Central Asia, The UNESCO Courier 2, Oct. 2001, available at http://www.unesco.org/courier/2001_10/uk/doss06.htm.
[161]. A Daily Review, supra note 39.
[162]. The Dublin Statement on Water and Sustainable Development, International Conference on Water and the Environment, Dublin, Ir., Jan. 1992, available at http://www.mgmt.okstate.edu/faculty/sharda/wcdreal/icwedece.html.
[163]. Cagnat, supra note 160.
[164]. The Dublin Statement, supra note 162.
[165]. Cagnat, supra note 160.
[166]. Id.
[167]. Id.
[168]. The Dublin Statement, supra note 162, princ. 4.
[169]. Prime Minister Faces Problems, supra note 31.
[170]. Hogan, supra note 39.
[171]. Bransten, supra note 40 (reporting that Kyrgyzstan has considered making water a commodity for years); see In Asia, Water is Worth Blood, Focus Central Asia, No. 52, 21-22, Nov. 1997, available at http://www.hartford-hwp.com/archives/53/047.html.
[172]. Bransten, supra note 40.
[173]. Boisson de Chazournes, supra note 11, at 68.
[174]. Chait, supra note 33, at 4.
[175]. Id. at 3.
[176]. Id. at 3.
[177]. Agreement Between the Governments of the Republic of Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, and the Republic of Uzbekistan on the Use of Water and Energy Resources of the Syr Darya Basin, Mar. 18, 1998 (O. Elizarova & T. Edilov trans.), available at http://www.epic.kz/w&e/agreem.htm.
[178]. Tajikistan is invited to join the agreement, but its recently ended civil war has hampered its ability to evaluate the agreement. Chait, supra note 33, at 1 n.1.
[179]. Id.
[180]. Id.
[181]. Id.
[182]. Agreement Between the Governments of the Republic of Kazakhstan, the Government of the Kyrgyz Republic, and the Government of the Republic of Uzbekistan on Joint and Complex Use Water and Energy Resources of the Naryn Syr Darya Cascade Reservoirs in 1998, Mar. 17, 1998, (O. Elizarova & T. Edilov trans.), available at http://www.epic.kz/w&e/agreem.htm [hereinafter Agreement on the Naryn Syr Darya Cascade Reservoirs].
[183]. Pannier, supra note 1.
[184]. Agreement on the Naryn Syr Darya Cascade Reservoirs, supra note 182.
[185]. Id.
[186]. Bransten, supra note 40 (quoting Duishen Mamatkhanov, Director of Kyrgyzstan’s Institute of Hydroenergy).
[187]. Bransten, supra note 40.
[188]. Id.
[189]. See id.
[190]. Uzbekistan has not paid for infrastructure upkeep as of 1997. Id.
[191]. See Central Asia: Water and Conflict, ICG Asia Report, No. 34, at 10 (May 30, 2002), at http://www.intl-crisis-group.org/projects/asia/centralasia/reports/A400668_30052002.pdf [hereinafter Water and Conflict].
[192]. Koichiev, supra note 31.
[193]. Khamidov, supra note 42.
[194]. See Chait, supra note 33, at 4 (noting that Kyrgyzstan used to receive coal, oil, and gas at extraction prices during Soviet times, but must now pay market prices for these fossil fuels. Meanwhile, water distribution levels have not changed).
[195]. Pannier, supra note 1.
[196]. Id.
[197]. See Koichiev, supra note 31.
[198]. See Horsman, supra note 3, at 75.
[199]. Hogan, supra note 45.
[200]. Id.
[201]. Pannier, supra note 1.
[202]. See Bea Hogan, Decreased Water Flow Threatens Cotton Crop, Peace in Region, EurasiaNet Environment (Aug. 2, 2000), at http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/environment/articles/eav080200.shtml; Koichiev, supra note 31.
[203]. See Cagnat, supra note 160.
[204]. Bransten, supra note 40; Cagnat, supra note 160; Khamidov, supra note 42.
[205]. Id.
[206]. Khamidov, supra note 42; see also A Daily Review, supra note 37.
[207]. Bransten, supra note 40.
[208]. Agreement on the Naryn Syr Darya Cascade Reservoirs, supra note 182.
[209]. See generally Micklin, supra note 7, at 29-36.
[210]. Id. at 29.
[211]. Id.
[212]. Id.
[213]. Id.
[214]. Id.
[215]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 30.
[216]. Id.
[217]. Id.
[218]. See generally id. at 30-32.
[219]. Id. at 30.
[220]. Id. at 30.
[221]. Id. at 30 (individuals in the region were predominantly Muslim and governed according to Islamic law).
[222]. Id. at 31.
[223]. Id. at 32.
[224]. Id. at 59.
[225]. See generally id. at 32-36.
[226]. Id.
[227]. Id. at 35.
[228]. Id. at 33.
[229]. Cagnat, supra note 160.
[230]. Id.
[231]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 60.
[232]. Id. at 9.
[233]. Id. at 59.
[234]. Id. at 60.
[235]. Id.
[236]. An eco-friendly corporation is sponsoring a contest for the development of an in-home energy meter that will teach a home’s occupants about the amount of energy that the home uses. The late Donella Meadows, an inspirational champion of the environment, suggests that this sort of metering device would influence homeowners to cut energy use much like her hybrid Honda influenced her driving habits. Donella Meadows, Give Me Feedback and I Will Change the World, Or At Least My Own Habits, The Global Citizen, (May 4, 2000), at http://iisd1.iisd.ca/pcdf/meadows/feedback.html. Local metering of water use in Central Asia not only would provide information as to actual water use rates, but could help educate and influence individual farmers to not over-irrigate through the increased feedback.
[237]. Micklin, supra note 7, at 61.
[238]. It is also difficult to charge a rate for water usage without knowing how much each farmer uses.
[239]. See Water and Conflict, supra note 191, at 12.