Business Structure, Regulation, and Deregulation
During the first 50 years of this century, the relative size of the
manufacturing sector consistently increased, while the
agricultural sector declined. Since 1950, a new trend has
developed. The relative sizes of both the service and government
sectors have increased, while agriculture and manufacturing have
generated a shrinking share of our national income.
It is not easy to categorize each industry as competitive or
noncompetitive. Nevertheless, empirical research on industrial
structure suggests that roughly 40 to 50 percent of our economy
is highly competitive, in the sense of rivalry. Another 20
percent of our output is generated by unregulated firms in
industries of medium or high concentration Highly regulated
industries account for nearly one quarter of our total output;
public-sector firms generate the remainder.
Foreign imports are an important and growing competitor in many
industries. Import penetration increased from 6.5 percent
in 1975 to 10.9 percent in 1984.
Antitrust legislation seeks to (a) maintain a competitive structure in
the unregulated private sector and (b) prohibit business
practices that are thought to stifle competition.
The Sherman, Clayton, and Federal Trade Commission Acts form the
foundation of antitrust policy in the United States. The Shermam
Act prohibits conspiracies to restrain trade and/or monopolize
an industry. The Clayton Act prohibits specific business
practices, such as price discrimination, tying contracts,
exclusive dealings, and mergers and acquisitions (as amended),
when they "substantially lessen competition or tend to
create a monopoly." As it has evolved through the year, the
Federal Trade Commission is concerned primarily with enforcing
consumer protection legislation, prohibiting deceptive
advertising, ad investigating industrial structure.
Most economists believe that antitrust policy in the United States has
promoted competition and reduced industrial concentration, but
not to any dramatic extent.
The breakup of AT&T reduced the cross-subsidy of local telephone
service by long-distance ratepayers, although the dispute about
how much fixed cost should be paid by long-distance users
remains unsettled.
To date, economists have been unable to develop a complete theory of
regulation. However, economic analysis does suggest that: (a)
the demand for regulation often stems from special interest and
redistribution considerations rather than from the pursuit of
economic efficiency; (b) regulation often fails to adjust to
changing market conditions; and (c) with the passage of time,
regulatory agencies are likely to adopt the views of the
interest groups they are supposed to regulate.
Traditional economic regulation has generally sought to fix prices and/or
influence industrial structure. During the 1970s, changing
market conditions and empirical studies generated widespread
dissatisfaction with economic regulation. Significant moves
toward deregulation were made in the late 1970s, particularly in
the trucking and airline industries. New entrants, intense
competition, and discount prices have accompanied the
deregulation of these industries.
In recent years, economic regulation has been relaxed, and social
regulatory activities have expanded rapidly. Social regulation
seeks to provide a cleaner, safer, healthier environment for
workers and consumers. Pursuit of this objective is
costly-higher product prices and higher taxes accompany such
regulation. Since the costs and particularly the benefits are
often difficult to measure and evaluate, the efficiency of
social regulatory programs is a controversial topic, and the
topic of much current research.