Government Antitrust and Regulation Policy
The firms in an oligopolistic industry, more so than in a purely
competitive or a monopolistically competitive industry, are
susceptible to collusion aimed at lessening or eliminating
competition among them so that each can earn a higher profit.
The government policy that deals with this threat to public
interest is called antitrust policy. It includes all government
action aimed at maintaining or restoring competition.
In reaction to a large amount of monopolization during the quarter of a
century after the Civil War, the first federal antitrust law,
the Sherman Antitrust Act, was passed in 1890. It prohibited the
restriction of competition, monopolization, and attempts to
monopolize.
In order to be more specific about firms' actions that are likely to
restrict competition, Congress passed the Clayton Act in 1914.
It dealt with four types of potentially anticompetitive business
practices: (a) price discrimination, (b) mergers, (c) exclusive
dealing and tying arrangements, and (d) interlocking
directorates. Two of the sections of the act were beefed up in
later amendments-the price- discrimination section in the
Robinson- Patman Act of 1936 and the merger section in the
Celler- Kefauver Antimerger Amendment of 1950.
The third major piece of antitrust legislation, the Federal Trade
Commission Act, was also passed in 1914. It prohibited unfair
methods of competition among firms, and after. the Wheeler Lea
Amendment in 1938, it also covered unfair and deceptive
practices toward consumers. In addition, the act set up a second
enforcement agency. The Federal Trade Commission was added to
the already established (1903) Antitrust Division of the Justice
Department.
The Sherman Antitrust Act prohibited monopolization or attempts to
monopolize, but it was left to the courts to interpret just what
that meant. From the time of the Standard Oil case in 1911 until
the Alcoa case in 1945, the Supreme Court adopted a "rule
of reason, " which focused on intent and conduct rather
than on the presence or absence of substantial monopoly control.
The Alcoa case and several others that followed in the late
1940s and early 1950s overturned the "rule of reason"
and made monopolization itself illegal. Since then some
backtracking toward a rule of reason has occurred.
Mergers that substantially lessen competition are illegal under the
Clayton Act, but due to certain loopholes the act had limited
power until the Celler-Kefauver Antimerger Amendment in 19 5 0.
During the 19 5 Os and 1960s the government impressively won a
number of horizontal and vertical merger cases. However, the
Supreme Court was not given a good opportunity to make a
definitive statement regarding conglomerate merger. Attempts in
the 1970's to pass new legislation that would pre vent huge
firms from making acquisitions failed. In the first half of the
1980s the "big is bad" philosophy was pretty well
discarded, and acquisitions by huge firms of other huge firms
were given the government's blessings.
Ever since the passage of the Sherman Antitrust Act in 1890, the courts
have ruled that price fixing-the agreement among competing firms
to restrict output in order to maintain high prices-is illegal.
The Supreme Court's blanket condemnation of price fixing has
been consistent.
A cartel is a collusive arrangement among sellers to fix output and
prices. Cartels are inherently unstable. It pays for individual
members to cheat because they can sell additional output at
monopoly prices. However when cheating be comes widespread, the
level of industry output in creases so much that monopoly prices
can no longer be maintained. The best-known cartel is OPEC. For
the decade beginning with 1973 it was quite successful in
restricting the supply of crude oil and raising its price. Since
that time the combination of lower demand, lower market share,
and cheating by various OPEC members has seriously
eroded OPEC's ability to control the world oil market.
Some industries, called "regulated industries, " are granted
monopoly status by the government. In return they are regulated
so that they are not able to take advantage of their monopoly
power. Such "monopoly regulation" is in addition to
the usual "social regulation, " to which most firms
are subject.
Most regulated industries are diagnosed as natural monopolies. A natural
monopoly is a market in which a single seller is required for
efficient production. Economies of scale are so great in
relation to the quantity demanded in the market that only one
firm can take full advantage of them. If more than one firm
operated in a natural monopoly market, price competition among
them would cause all but the strongest firm to leave the market.
The government attempts to recognize an industry as a natural monopoly
before firms begin operation and ruinous competition takes
place. In such instances the government may establish a public
enterprise, but more likely it will grant a private firm public
utility status and then regulate it. Regulation takes place by
both state and federal regulatory commissions. The four most
prominent federal regulatory commissions are the ICC, FCC, SEC,
and FERC.
Regulatory commissions concern them selves mainly with the prices that
public utilities charge. They regulate both the level of rates
and the structure of rates. They seek to set a rate level that
gives public utility firms a fair return on a fairly valued rate
base. This is usually interpreted as nor-mal profit on the
replacement cost of a firm's capital. Regarding the structure of
rates, firms have an incentive to charge different rates
according to the class of customer, the quantity purchased, and
the time of delivery. Regulatory commissions encourage price
differentials based on cost differences, but try to prevent
price discrimination.
Until the 1960s few economists and government officials questioned the
appropriateness of regulation. But in the 1960s and more so in
the 1970s, suggestions to deregulate were frequently heard.
Because of technological change, some industries no longer were
natural monopolies. Some natural monopoly industries were
recognized to be contestable markets, in which regulation
actually prevented
new firms from entering and offering better service and lower
prices. The public also be came more disenchanted with
regulation because of high prices and a greater recognition that
regulated firms had in many cases captured their regulators
Beginning in the late 1970s various degrees of deregulation
occurred in many public utility industries, the outstanding
example being the domestic airline industry.