International Finance and the Foreign Exchange Market
The foreign exchange market is a highly organized market in which
currencies of different countries are bought and sold.
The exchange rate is the price of one national currency in terms
of another. The exchange rate permits consumers in one country
to translate the prices of foreign goods into units of their own
currency.
When international trade takes place, it is usually necessary for one
country to convert its currency to the currency of its trading
partner. Imports of goods, services, and assets (both real and
financial) by the United States generate a demand for foreign
currency with which to pay for these items. On the other hand,
exports of goods, services, and assets supply foreign currency
to the exchange market because foreigners exchange their
currency for the dollars needed to purchase the export items.
The value of a nation's currency on the exchange market is in equilibrium
when the supply of the currency (generated by imports-the sale
of goods, services, and assets to foreigners) is just equal to
the demand for the currency (generated by exports-the purchasing
of goods, services, and assets from foreigners).
Under a flexible rate system, if there is an excess supply of dollars
(excess demand for foreign currencies) on the foreign exchange
market, the value of the dollar will depreciate relative to
other currencies. A depreciation will make foreign goods more
expensive to U.S. consumers and U.S. goods cheaper to
foreigners, reducing the value of our imports and increasing the
value of our exports until equilibrium is restored. On the other
hand, an excess demand for dollars (excess supply of foreign
currencies) will cause the dollar to appreciate stimulating
imports and discouraging exports until equilibrium is restored.
With flexible exchange rates, a nation's currency tends to appreciate
when (a) rapid economic growth abroad (and slow growth at home)
stimulates exports relative to imports, (b) the rate of domestic
inflation is below that of the nation's trading partners, and
(c) domestic real interest rates increase relative to one's
trading partners. The reverse of these conditions will cause a
nation's currency to depreciate.
Unanticipated restrictive monetary policy will raise the real interest
rate, reduce the rate of inflation, and, at least temporarily,
reduce aggregate demand and the growth of income. These factors
will in turn cause the nation's currency to appreciate on the
foreign exchange market. In contrast, expansionary monetary
policy will result in a currency depreciation.
Fiscal policy tends to generate conflicting influences on the exchange
rate. To the extent that expansionary fiscal policy (larger
budget deficits) stimulates income, it promotes imports relative
to exports, causing a currency to depreciate. However, to the
extent expansionary fiscal policy increases the real interest
rate of a nation, it causes an appreciation of a nation's
currency due to an inflow of foreign investment. The analysis is
symmetrical for restrictive fiscal policy.
During the period from 1944 to 197 1, most of the nations of the free
world operated under a system of fixed exchange rates. Under
this system, if the value of the goods, services, and capital
assets exported to foreigners is less than the value of the
items imported, there is an excess supply of the country's
currency on the foreign exchange market. When this happens, the
country must (a) devalue its currency, (b) take action to reduce
imports (for example, heighten its trade barriers), or (c)
pursue a restrictive macropolicy designed to increase interest
rates and retard inflation. During the period when the fixed
rates were in effect, corrective action taken to maintain the
rates was often in conflict with the goals of maximum freedom in
international markets and the macropolicy objective of full
employment.
Prior to World War 1, most countries set the value of their currency in
terms of gold. When trade was conducted under the gold standard,
the gold stock of a nation would fall if it imported more than
it exported. The decline in the stock of gold would decrease the
nation's money supply, causing prices to fall and making the
nation's goods more competitive on the international market. In
contrast, if a nation was a net exporter, its stock of gold
would rise, causing inflation and making the nation's goods less
competitive on the international market. How ever, alterations
in the supply of gold often caused abrupt shifts in income and
employment. The gold standard was abandoned in 1914.
The balance of payments accounts record the flow of payments between a
country and other countries. Transactions (for example, imports)
that supply a nation's currency to the foreign exchange market
are recorded as debit items. Transactions (for example, exports)
that generate a demand for the nation's currency on the foreign
exchange market are recorded as credit items
In aggregate, the balance of payment accounts must balance since the
accounts are kept according to the principles of double-entry
book keeping. Thus, (a) the current account balance plus (b) the
capital ac count balance plus (c) the official reserve account
balance must equal zero. However, the individual components of
the accounts need not balance. A deficit in one area implies an
offsetting surplus in other areas.
Under a pure flexible rate system, there will not be any official reserve
account transaction. Under these circumstances, a current
account deficit implies a capital account surplus (and vice
versa). Interestingly, an economy offering attractive investment
opportunities to foreigners will tend to run a capital account
surplus, which also implies a current account deficit under a
flexible rate system.
Since 1973, most countries have operated under a managed flexible rate
system. It is a managed system because the major industrial
nations have used their official reserve balances in an effort
to moderate swings in exchange rates. Nevertheless, market
forces now play the major role in the determination of exchange
rates among the major industrial nations. Given the severe
shocks that international markets have suffered since it was
instituted in 1973, the current system appears to be working
reasonably well.