Labor Unions and Collective Bargaining
Union membership grew rapidly during the 1935-55 period. In 1955,
approximately one out of three nonfarm workers in the United
States belonged to a union. During the last three decades, union
membership has waned. In 1984, only one in six nonfarm workers
were union members.
The strike is a major source of union power. A strike can cause the
employer to lose sales while incurring continuing fixed cost.
The threat of a strike, particularly when inventories are low,
is an inducement for the employer to consent to the union's
terms.
A strike is also costly to employees. Strike funds are usually inadequate
to deal with a prolonged strike. The loss of just a few
paychecks can impose extreme hardship on most families. The
potential cost of a strike to both union and management provides
each with an incentive to bargain seriously to avoid a work
stoppage.
Agreement on most collective bargaining contracts is reached without a
work stoppage. Since World War 11, the number of work hours lost
due to strikes is less than three tenths of the total work
time-and the proportion of work time lost due to strikes has
been declining.
There are three basic methods a union can use to increase the wages of
its members: (a) restrict the supply of competitive inputs,
including nonunion workers; (b) apply bargaining power enforced
by a strike or threat of one; and (c) increase the demand for
the labor service of union members.
When there are a large number of employees competing for labor services,
each employer will have to pay the market wage rate to keep
employees from shifting to higher-wage alternatives. However,
when monopsony is present, the single purchaser of labor may be
able to profit by restricting employment and paying a wage rate
that is less than the marginal revenue generated by the labor.
Under these circumstances, a wage floor established by a union
can result in both higher wages and increased employment.
If a union is going to increase the wages of its members without
experiencing a significant reduction in employment, the demand
for union labor must be inelastic. The strength of a union is
enhanced if (a) there is an absence of good substitutes for this
service, (b) the demand for the good it produces is highly
inelastic, (c) the union labor input is a small share of the
total cost of production, and/or (d) the supply of any available
substitute is highly inelastic. An absence of these conditions
weakens the power of the union.
Studies suggest that the earnings of union members exceed those of
similar nonunion members by between 10 and 25 percent. Research
using data from the 7Os tends to place the differential closer
to the higher figure. The most powerful unions have been able to
obtain even larger wage gains for their members. Some weaker
unions, unable to restrict the supply of nonunion workers (or
products made by them), have had little impact on wages. Most of
the real wage increases of union workers have probably been
obtained at the expense of nonunion workers and consumers.
There is no indication that unions have significantly increased the share
of national income going to labor in general. The real wages of
workers are a reflection of their productivity rather than the
result of union action or power. There is little reason to
believe that unions enhance worker productivity- they may even
retard it.
An increase in the wages of union members will either reduce expenditures
on goods produced by nonunion labor or increase the supply of
nonunion labor. In either case, the secondary effects of higher
union wages will tend to reduce prices in the nonunion sector.
Thus, there is no reason to believe that unions cause sustained
increases in the general price level (inflation).
Unions in the United States have helped defend employees against a sense
of powerlessness, unimportance, alienation, and insecurity, and
against arbitrary behavior by management. The union movement is
primarily responsible for our system of "industrial
jurisprudence." Many think these nonpecuniary factors are
far more important than the impact of unions on wages.