Labor, Wages, and Collective Bargaining
Economists study the supply and demand for labor under different sets of
conditions. Companies may hire workers in competitive or
monopsonistic labor markets, and they may sell their output in
competitive or monopolistic product markets. An individual
company in a purely competitive product market cannot affect the
price of the goods or services that it sells, nor can an
individual company in a purely competitive labor market affect
the wage rate that it pays to its workers. However, an
individual company that is a monopolist in the product market
does affect the price of the goods or services that it sells,
and an individual company that is a monopsonist in the labor
market affects the wage rate that it pays.
A company that hires workers in a purely competitive labor market faces a
horizontal supply and MFC curve. lt will want to hire more
workers if it sells its goods or services competitively than if
it is a monopolist in the product market. This is the case
because in a monopolistic product market a company's MRP curve
is steeper than in a purely competitive one and so will
intersect its MFC curve at a lower level of employment.
An individual worker's supply curve of labor is expected to be positively
sloped at most, but not necessarily all, wage rates. At very
high wage rates it may "bend back," or become
negative, as the worker's income effect outweighs his or her
substitution effect.
A market-supply curve of labor slopes upward because as the wage rate for
that particular occupation rises in relation to the wage rates
for other occupations, more and more people will offer their
services for that occupation. A market demand curve for labor is
derived by aggregating all of the individual firms MRP curves,
The equilibrium wage rate and quantity of workers employed in a
labor market is identified by the intersection of the
market-supply curve with the market-demand curve. In a purely
competitive labor market, that wage rate will be accepted as the
going wage, and each individual firm will be able to hire as
many or as few workers as it wishes to hire at that wage.
Individual firms that are monopsonists in the labor market face
positively sloped supply curves of labor. This means that in
order to attract more workers, they have to pay higher wage
rates. Their MFC of hiring an additional worker is, how ever,
higher than the wage rate paid to that additional worker, since
all of the workers hired earlier must also be paid the higher
wage rate. As in competitive labor markets, the equilibrium
number of workers that a monopsonist will hire is found at the
point where the monopsonist's MFC curve intersects its MRP
curve. But, whereas for a purely competitive employer, MFC is
equal to the equilibrium wage rate, for a monopsonistic
employer, MFC is above the equilibrium wage rate.
Labor unions are collective organizations whose primary goals are to
improve the wages and working conditions of their employee
members. ft was difficult for them to become established in the
United States. At first many people resented them and considered
them a threat to the American free enterprise system.
Before the formation of the AF of L in 1886, American unions were fairly
local and were often involved in political actions. In a sense,
they were on a roller coaster, doing well during prosperous
times but being all but wiped out during recessions. With the
founding of the AF of L came the beginning of business unionism.
It was not until the Great Depression of the 193Os that public opinion
swung over to support the union cause. This change of heart led
to the passage of two important pro-union laws, the Norris
-LaGuardia Act and the Wagner- Connery Act. After World War 11,
Congress passed a somewhat compensating pro-employer labor law,
called the Taft-Hartley Act.
An internal union struggle between craft unions, representing particular
types of skilled workers, and industrial unions, representing
all the workers in an industry, had been festering during the
first three decades of the twentieth century. This struggle came
to a head in 1938 when the AF of L expelled the CfO from its
ranks. It was not until 1955 that the two finally merged.
The problem of corruption and racketeering in some unions led to the
passage of the Landrum-Griffin Act in 1959. The problem of
racial discrimination was a major concern of many unions in the
early 1960s. Unions supported the efforts to pass the Civil
Rights Act of 1964.
Union membership increased during the 1960s, held fairly constant during
the 1970s, and fell dramatically in the 1980s. The 1960s and
1970s saw a great change in the composition of union membership.
The percentage of private firm employees who were union members
declined, whereas the percentage of public employees who were
unionized rose.
Collective bargaining is the approach used by labor unions to negotiate
with employers or their representatives. The issues in
collective bargaining fall into two broad categories: (a) the
conditions of employment, such as wage issues, fringe benefits
and work standards, and (b) the relationship between the union
and management. The process of collective bargaining often calls
for a great show of strength on both sides. The ultimate weapon
of a union is the strike, which may be supplemented by picketing
and boycotts.
Unions have an impact on wage rates. Just how much they are able to raise
wage rates is difficult to determine. When bargaining takes
place in purely competitive labor markets, unions may achieve
higher wage rates through restricting the supply of labor,
bargaining for an above-equilibrium wage rate, or raising the
demand for labor. When bargaining takes place in a monopsonistic
labor market, we cannot predict just how high the equilibrium
wage rate will be. The relative power of the union and
management along with the policies that they follow will dictate
the result of the bargaining.
Government also has an impact on wage rates. Labor laws have strengthened
unions and in turn have tended to raise wages. Whenever the
government increases or decreases taxes that employees or
employers must pay, it has an effect on both employment and wage
rates.
Government affects some wage rates when it sets a minimum wage, or a
lower limit on the wage rate that firms are allowed to pay.
Generally, firms in industries affected by minimum-wage
legislation are in fairly competitive labor markets, so that
although the legislation increases the wage rates of some
low-wage employees, it also reduces employment. In monopsonistic
labor markets, the result of a minimum wage may be not only to
increase the wage rate of low-wage employees but also to bring
about a higher level of employment.
The general proposition that an equilibrium wage rate in a labor market
is determined by the interaction of the forces of supply and
demand hides a great many variables that operate to pro duce
wage differentials. These variables may be placed in three
categories: (a) the qualifications of the workers, (b) the
desirability of the job, and (c) the institutions that surround
the labor market. In most cases, workers who possess desirable
qualifications will receive higher wages than workers who do not
possess them. Workers who accept undesirable jobs are usually
paid a compensating wage differential. Labor market institutions
that stem from union action, government action, geographic labor
immobility, and discrimination affect the degree of imperfection
in a labor market and, in turn, wage rates.