Monopoly
Pure monopoly is an extreme market type in which there is only a single
seller. No acceptable substitutes are available, and entry into
the market is barred. The pure monopolist and the industry are
one and the same.
Actual monopoly is a real-world form of monopoly. An actual monopolist is
the only seller in its market, yet it competes with rivals in
other markets, recognizes potential competition, and may be
subject to more or less government regulation.
Actual monopolies may or may not be " government- enforced. "
Government- enforced monopolies may be firms that have received
an exclusive franchise from the government or that have been
granted a government patent. Actual monopolies may or may not be
"natural monopolies. " Natural monopolies are those
that owe their monopoly status to the particular cost conditions
in their industries. Economies of scale are so important in
relation to demand in such markets that only a single firm can
take full advantage of them.
Monopoly control refers to the degree of control or power that a firm
possesses over the price of the product that it sells. All firms
except those that are in purely competitive industries possess
some degree of monopoly control.
A pure monopolist is expected to face a negatively sloped demand curve.
Its marginal - revenue curve slopes beneath its demand curve
because price must be lowered in order to sell more and because
the new lower price must be charged for all units of output to
all of the monopolist's customers.
When demand is elastic, marginal revenue is positive, and total revenue
is rising. When demand is unitary elastic, marginal revenue is
zero, and total revenue is at its maximum. When demand is
inelastic, marginal revenue is negative, and total revenue is
falling.
A pure monopolist will maximize its profit at the level of output at
which its total revenue exceeds its total cost by the maximum
amount, which is also where its marginal cost and marginal
revenue are equated. The price it will charge is determined by
the demand curve that it faces.
In the short run, a pure monopolist may experience an economic profit,
just a normal profit, or an economic loss. If its revenue is not
enough to cover its variable cost, it will shut down. In the
long run, a pure monopolist may experience an economic profit or
just a normal profit.
Given a certain market demand for a product and a certain cost to produce
it, pure monopoly as compared with pure competition offers its
consumers less output and higher prices. Purely competitive
firms offer consumers greater welfare than does pure monopoly
since the purely competitive firm charges a price that is equal
to marginal cost, whereas the monopolist charges a price in
excess of marginal cost.
More efficient resource allocation is provided by purely competitive
firms as compared with pure monopoly. This fact is demonstrated
by forcing a transfer of resources from a purely competitive
industry in long-run equilibrium to a pure monopoly market also
in long-run equilibrium. Because price is equal to marginal cost
in pure competition and price is higher than marginal cost in
pure monopoly, a given dollar value of resource transfer will
increase the combined value of output produced by the two
industries.
Pure monopolists may operate on higher average-total- cost curves than do
their counterparts in pure competition because they are not
pushed by competitors to produce at the lowest cost possible.
However, a monopolist may produce at lower average total cost
than its counterparts in pure competition because it is large
enough to capture economies of scale not available to smaller
pure competitors.
Through effective research and development, the average-total-cost curve
may be shifted downward in the very long run. There is no clear
answer as to whether or not monopoly will foster such
progressive actions. On the one hand, a monopolist is not pushed
by competitors and may simply not bother, but on the other hand,
monopolists have the incentive of long-run economic profit and
probably the money to carry out research.
Pure monopoly may or may not be consistent with equity. Monopolies owned
largely by a few individuals or families promote an unequal
distribution of income and wealth. But when the stock of
monopolies is widely held and includes large numbers of widows
and orphans, they cannot be condemned on the basis of equity.
When a firm sells the same product at the same time to different
customers at different prices, there is a price differential.
Price discrimination takes place when a price differential is
not justified by a difference in cost to the seller. In order to
practice price discrimination, the seller must possess monopoly
control, must be able to separate buyers into different markets
with different price elasticities of demand, and must be able to
prevent low-price buyers from reselling the product to
high-price buyers.
By practicing price discrimination, a monopolist may be able to improve
its profit position. It may be able to earn more profit than it
would if it were simply equating its marginal cost and marginal
revenue and charging a single price deter mined by its demand
curve.
The practice of price discrimination some times is detrimental to
society's welfare and at other times is quite beneficial. Price
discrimination may serve as a vehicle for an already powerful
firm to gain even greater monopoly control and may also be used
as a way to eliminate price competition in markets where such
competition is socially desirable. On the other hand, price
discrimination may be used to provide greater equity and also to
lessen monopoly control.