The Intermediate Cases: Monopolistic Competition and
Oligopoly
The distinguishing characteristics of monopolistic competition are (a)
firms that produce differentiated products, (b) low barriers to
entry into and exit from the market, and (c) a substantial
number of independent, rival firms.
Monopolistically competitive firms face a gently downward-sloping demand
curve. They often use product quality, style, convenience of
location, advertising, and price as competitive weapons. Since
all rivals within a monopolistically competitive industry are
free to duplicate another's products (or services), the demand
for the product of any one firm is highly elastic.
A profit-maximizing firm will expand output as long as marginal revenue
exceeds marginal cost. Thus, a firm under monopolistic
competition will lower its price so that output can be expanded
until MR = MC. The price charged by the profit-maximizing
monopolistic competitor will be greater than its marginal cost.
If monopolistic competitors are making economic profits, rival firms will
be induced to enter the market. They will expand the supply of
the product (and similar products), enticing some customers away
from established firms. The demand curve faced by an individual
firm will fall (shift inward) until the profits have been
eliminated.
Economic losses will cause monopolistic competitors to exit from the
market. The demand for the products of each remaining firm will
rise (shift outward) until the losses have been eliminated.
Since barriers to entry are low, firms in a monopolistically competitive
industry will make only normal profits in the long-run. In the
short run, they may make either economic profits or losses,
depending on market conditions.
Traditional economic theory has emphasized that monopolistic com petition
is inefficient because (a) price exceeds marginal cost at the
long-run equilibrium output level; (b) long-run average cost is
not minimized; and (c) excessive advertising is sometimes
encouraged. However, other economists have argued more recently
that this criticism is misdirected. According to the newer view,
firms under monopolistic competition have an incentive to (a)
produce efficiently; (b) undertake production if and only if
their actions will increase the value of resources used; and (c)
offer a variety of products.
Oligopolistic market structure is characterized by (a) an interdependence
among firms, (b) substantial economies of scale that result in
only a small number of firms in the industry, and (c)
significant barriers to entry. Oligopolists may produce either
homogeneous or differentiated
products.
There is no general theory of price, output, and equilibrium for
oligopolistic markets. If rival oligopolists acted totally
independently of their competitors, they would drive price down
to the level of cost of production. Alternatively, if they used
collusion to obtain perfect cooperation, price would rise to the
level that a monopolist would charge. The actual outcome lies
between these two extremes.
Collusion is the opposite of competition. Oligopolists have a strong
incentive to collude and raise their prices. However, the
interests of individual firms will conflict with those of the
industry as a whole. Since the demand curve faced by individual
firms is far more elastic than the industry demand curve, each
firm could gain by cutting its price (or raising product
quality) by a small amount so that it could attract customers
from rivals. If several firms tried to do this, however, the
collusive agreement would break down.
Oligopolistic firms- are less likely to collude successfully against the
interests of consumers if (a) the number of rival firms is
large; (b) it is costly to prohibit competitors from offering
secret price cuts (or quality improvements) to customers; (c)
entry barriers are low; (d) market demand conditions tend to be
unstable; and/or (e) the threat of antitrust action is present.
Competition can come from potential, as well as actual rivals. If entry
and exit are not expensive, and if there are no legal barriers
to entry, the theory of contestable markets indicates that
competitive result may occur even if only one or a few firms are
actually in the market.
The kinked demand curve helps explain why oligopolistic price may tend to
be inflexible. Under the basic assumption of the kinked demand
curve-rivals will match price reductions but not increases-a
firm's price rise leads to a sharp reduction in its sales, but a
price reduction attracts a few new customers. Thus, once a price
is established, it remains inflexible for extended periods of
time.
Analysis of concentration ratios suggest that, on balance, there has been
an increase in the competitiveness of the U.S. economy in recent
decades.
Accounting profits as a share of stockholder equity are probably slightly
greater in highly concentrated industries than in those that are
less concentrated. The relationship between profits and
concentration however, is not a close one. This suggests that
several other factors, such as changing market conditions,
quality competition, risk, and ability to exclude rivals, are
the major determinants of profitability.
The after-tax accounting profits of business firms average about 5 cents
of each dollar of sales, substantially less than most Americans
believe to be the case. Accounting profits average approximately
12 percent of stockholder equity. This rate of return
(accounting profit) provides investors with the incentive to
sacrifice current consumption, assume the risk of undertaking a
business venture, and supply the funds to purchase buildings,
machines, and other assets.