The Clayton and
Robinson-Patman Acts
The Clayton Act sought to prohibit mergers
insofar as they tended to lessen com petition. But it said nothing about
purchases of one company's assets, rather than its stocks, by another company.
In 1950, however, the Celler-Kefauver amendment to the Act targeted purchases
of assets, as well.
Mergers often create economies of scale.
Horizontal mergers enlarge firms by joining former competitors. Vertical
mergers link separate stages in the manufacture or marketing of a product or
service. Conglomerate mergers help firms bear risk. Often, it is not obvious
how to classify any particular merger. Courts must determine cross-elasticity
of supply and demand to define the outer limits of the relevant markets.
In a horizontal merger case, the
plaintifF seeks to prove that the merger produces "undue
concentration" in the relevant market. Under the foreclosure theory, a
vertical merger threatens competition by blocking third parties' access to
suppliers or sales outlets. Conglomerate mergers have been successfully
challenged on three grounds: potential competition, entrenchment, and
reciprocity.
The Clayton Act also outlaws tie-ins,
exclusive dealing, and reciprocal deals. All three potentially harm competition
by interfering with the buyer's or seller's freedom of choice. For a tie-in to
be illegal, the tied products must be distinct, the seller must have market
power in the tying product's market, and the tie-in must affect more than a
minimal amount of commerce.
There have been two very different
approaches to merger policy. Advocates of economic analysis regard most mergers
favorably, insisting that the competitiveness of a market does not depend upon
any particular balance of large and small firms. Advocates of multivalued
analysis regard the accumulation of gigantic assets as suspicious even if it
proves no immediate threat of uncompetitive pricing
Adopting the economic approach, the
Reagan Administration Justice Department has focused on market concentration,
setting forth the conditions that lead to collusion or monopoly. Its revised
1984 guidelines measure market concentration with the Herfindahl-Hirschman
Index (HHI), which takes account of the variation in market share among the
firms in a market.
Price discrimination can cause injury to
competition among sellers or buyers. Predatory pricing typically occurred when
a national firm targeted certain geographic markets for cut rates that were
intended to hurt local competition. The main force behind the 1936 amendment
was small-business groups concerned about competition at the buyer's level from
chain stores. Sellers may rebut a charge of price discrimination by showing
that they sought to meet a rival's low price. Differences in price may also be
justified by differences in the seller's costs associated with the two sales.
Under the 1936 Robinson-Patman Act, an
amendment to the Clayton Act, a prima facie price discrimination case requires
actual, nearly simultaneous sales of tangible goods of "like grade and
quality, " to at least two different customers, at directly or indirectly
different prices. The Act specifically outlaws brokerage allowances,
promotional allowances, and special services or side items provided to some
buyers and not others.
Many scholars have charged that the
Robinson-Patman Act is overly technical, poorly written, and hostile to
competition. The prospect of treble damages suits under the Act has had a
dampening effect on competition, but courts, and public opinion, are becoming
increasingly tolerant of competitive pricing.