The Foreign Sector
Transactions with foreign
countries give rise to a market for foreign exchange, since both domestic and
foreign parties want to pay and be paid in their own currency. The price of
foreign exchange in terms of the domestic currency is called the foreign
exchange rate.
Under fixed foreign exchange
rate systems, governments announce levels at which they intend to maintain
foreign exchange rates, and they maintain these rates by a variety of means,
including intervention in the market with reserves of foreign exchange and
gold. Foreign exchange rate adjustments are reserved for fundamental changes in
balance of international payments positions.
Under completely flexible foreign
exchange rate systems, the foreign exchange rate is left free to respond to the
forces of demand and supply in the market and automatically balances
international payments.
The Bretton Woods system of
fixed foreign exchange rates, on which the world operated from 1946 to early
1973, developed the basic flaw of being unable to produce the adjustments in
foreign exchange rates needed to accommodate fundamental changes in balance of
payments positions among major trading nations. This meant, on the one hand,
that the system was not durable, and it eventually collapsed. More important,
it meant that nations which developed chronic deficits under the system, such
as the United States and the United Kingdom, were led, before the collapse, to
improve their payments positions by means which compromised full employment,
economic growth, and free trade.
In 1973, the United States moved
to a more flexible foreign exchange rate system, a system often termed managed
float. This system is not completely flexible, since the Federal Reserve and
foreign central banks regularly intervene in the market with supplies of
foreign exchange to influence foreign exchange rates. However, there is no
commitment to maintain fixed foreign exchange rates, as with the Bretton Woods
type of system, or even to maintain fluctuations in rates within a specified
range.
The great advantage of managed
float and flexible foreign exchange rate systems is that they can produce the
adjustments in foreign exchange rates needed to accommodate fundamental
disturbances to international payments positions. This eliminates the need for compromises of full employment,
economic growth, and free trade by nations whose currencies weaken over time.
Nations in these circumstances can still compromise these goals in favor of an
overvalued currency if they choose to do so in order to avoid the
terms-of-trade and inflation effects of a depreciating currency.
Completely flexible foreign
exchange rate systems have the disadvantage that they may produce very wide
short-term fluctuations in foreign exchange rates. Such fluctuations are
disruptive to activity levels in export, import, and import-competing
industries, since they affect the price-competitiveness of the firms engaged in
these industries. If participation in export and import industries is
discouraged as a result, the level of international trade declines, and a
portion of the gains nations can make from international trade is lost. In
addition, sharp short-term currency depreciations produce terms-of-trade and
inflation effects not required by the nation's fundamental international
payments position. Managed float systems diminish these problems to the extent
the managers are able to smooth out short-term fluctuations in foreign exchange
rates.