A Federal Solution to the Conflict
in Sudan
Dr. M A Fazal
[Initially
written in 2002 (updated subsequently)]
[Based on the federal model constructed in ‘A Federal Constitution
for the United Kingdom – An Alternative to Devolution” (Dartmouth/Ashgate,
1997) by M A Fazal.]
The conflict between the north and the south of Sudan is
summed up by the statement:
“Broadly the war pits rebel forces seeking more autonomy for the
mainly Animist and Christian south against the Muslim government
in the north. Oil and ideology have further complicated the conflict
in Africa’s largest country”.
This sums up the issues underlying the conflict between
the north and the south of Sudan.
Background
The origin of the civil war in Sudan dates back to the 1950s. The three southern provinces of Al Istiwai, Bahr al Ghazal and Aali an Nil were centres
of opposition to Khartoum’s authority since the days before independence. After independence in 1956, southerners resented
the replacement of British administrators in the south with northern Sudanese. The problem concerned the status
of the civil service. On August 18th 1955, the
Equatoria Corps, a military unit composed of southerners,
mutinied at Torit. This marked the beginning of the first war in southern Sudan. By
the late 1960s, the war had resulted in the deaths of about 500,000 people. Several hundred thousand more
southerners fled into the forests or escaped to refugee camps in neighbouring countries.
In February 1962 owing to the harsh treatment of southern civilians by northern armed forces,
better educated southerners (who had served in government posts or were
teachers) formed the Sudan Africa Closed Districts National Union. In April
1963 the Group changed its name to the Sudan African National Union (SANU)
and advocated outright independence for southern Sudan.
Meanwhile numerous less educated southerners formed guerrilla bands
the Anya Nya which began
activities in 1963. By 1969 they had established foreign contacts and obtained weapons and training. Thus the Anya Nya
developed into an effective military force. By
1971 it controlled most rural areas in the south. The military
leaders of the Anya Nya
formed a political organisation, the Southern Sudan Liberation Movement (SSLM),
Jaafar Nimeiri who became the President of Sudan in 1969 negotiated an agreement
with the SSLM in 1972 in Addis Ababa (the capital of Ethiopia).
Under the provisions of the Addis Abba Accord the central government and the
SSLM agreed to a ceasefire and Khartoum recognised the regional autonomy of the three southern provinces. During the course of the negotiations
the SSLM had demanded a federal state with a separate southern government.
After signing the accord, Nimeiri issued a decree providing for the establishment of a Southern regional assembly.
Throughout the 1970s the Nimeiri government
observed the Addis Ababa Accord fairly and faithfully and the south’s relative
political freedom contrasted sharply with the authoritarian rule in the rest of the country.
However, subsequently the Addis Ababa Accord was undermined for the same reasons
as had prompted the southern rebellion in the 1960s, namely the fears that the north was determined to force Arabisation and Islamisation on
the south. Owing to the increasing influence of the Muslim Brotherhood (the right-wing Islamic party) over the
central government policies Nimeiri virtually abrogated
the Addis Ababa Accord by dissolving the Southern Regional
Assembly in 1981 (US Library of Congress Country: Sudan).
The proportion of the main religious groups in Sudan is as follows: Sunni Muslims: 70%; indigenous beliefs: 25%; Christians:
5%. The problem has always been one of reconciliation among these religious
groups. The SPLM is opposed to the application of Sharia
law (the Islamic religious law) to the non-Muslims. In February 1983 a mutiny broke out among the southern
troops. In August 1983 a former colonel in the Sudanese army, John
Garang, formed the Sudanese People’s Liberation
Movement (the SPLM). In September 1983 when Nimeiri
imposed the Sharia over the whole country, the SPLM
rebellion coordinated by its newly formed military wing the Sudanese People’s
Liberation Army (the SPLA) turned into a full scale war – a conflict that has lasted until now. It is estimated
that about 2 million people have been killed since 1983. More than 4.5 million
have been internally displaced. Khartoum alone has
a refugee population of 4 million. One million Sudanese are living in exile in other countries. These
are the figures out of a total population of 30 million in Sudan (Amnesty
International: Sudan).The figures are indicative of the extent of damage caused by the civil war.
Unlike its predecessor the SSLM sought not secession from Sudan but
a solution based on a secular, democratic and a federal political system.
Since one of the first acts of the transitional government that overthrew
Nimeiri in 1985 was to suspend the enforcement of the Sharia law promulgated in September 1983, the SPLM
agreed to negotiate with the central government. In 1986 the SPLM leaders
and several northerners met at the Ethopian Koka Dam where they signed an important declaration. Nevertheless
the primary issue separating the SPLM from the northern parties - the role of the Sharia remained unresolved. That issue remains still unresolved despite subsequent attempts to resolve it.
Discovery of Oil and Gas
Sudan is
called the potential “breadbasket of the Arab world”. Large-scale mechanised
agriculture expanding into southern Kordofan, a huge influx of international capital and
the discovery of oil and gas ought to bring into reality this vision. Nonetheless
oil seems to have been the final spark for uprisings and the formation of armed opposition in Sudan such
as Anyana II and the SPLA in 1984. The SPLA’s first armed activities in 1984 were targeted at the
workers of the oil company Chevron which began operations in Red Sea and near Bentiu, Makkal and Muglad in south and south western Sudan in 1974. In 1980 Nimeiri embarked
on “re-division” of the south from one autonomous unit to three states. A map attached to the Regional Government Bill
put the area where oil had been found into the northern part of
Sudan. His creation of a new “Unity” state around Bentiu
to prise it from the south caused political upheaval among southerners, as
did the presidential decree that an oil refinery was to be built at Kosti,
in the north, instead of in Bentiu.
Despite the SPLA-Government agreement negotiated under the Machakos Protocol signed on 20th July 2002, the SPLA launched military strikes in the oil-rich areas. According to the SPLA statement of 2 October 2002,
one of its commando units mounted an attack on the oil collection and production
complex in Heglig and destroyed the main station, thereby cutting off oil supplies to Khartoum. Heglig accounts for the bulk of Sudan’s
oil production running currently at 240,000 barrels per day. It came on stream in August 1999 making Sudan an
oil-exporting country. If this were to happen, that would strike a blow to
the government’s plans to boost production to 300,000 barrels per day by the
end of 2003 and to more than 450,000 barrels per day by 2005. Heavy fighting was also reported from
the Western Upper Nile regions at about the same time. The SPLA claimed in a press statement issued
on 2nd
October 2002 that the attack on Heglig was codenamed “Our Petrol”. “It targets the government
plan to pillage our people’s resources”. In its statement the SPLA renewed
its warnings to all oil companies, telling them to halt oil production until
a just peace was achieved. The statement said that all oil contracts would
be renegotiated if a peace deal were to be signed. According to the latest press reports
at the time of writing this paper, the Government forces have recaptured those oil-rich
areas and peace talks have been resumed under the auspices of the Inter-Governmental
Authority on Development following a temporary agreement to cease hostilities.
Because of these hostilities, according to the press report of
30 October 2002, Talisman Energy Inc., the Canadian oil company, sold its
Sudan oil interest to a subsidiary of India's national oil company, Oil and
Natural Gas Corporation Ltd., for $758 million. Talisman had been involved
in Sudan for four years through a 25 per cent stake in the greater Nile Petroleum
Operating Co. production and pipeline project. The rest of the development
is owned by state-owned oil companies from China (40 per cent), Malaysia (30
per cent) and Sudan (five per cent). Canada’s Tailsman Energy Inc. finally
completed a deal on 9th March 2003 to sell its oil interests in Sudan for
about $ 1.2 billion to a subsidiary of India’s national oil company.
This raises the question whether mines and minerals including oil and gas should come
under the federal or provincial jurisdiction in the event of a federal solution to the conflict in Sudan being achieved.
Solutions to the Sharia Question
The question of the role of Sharia has been
the stumbling bloc in all negotiations between the Government of Sudan and the SPLM/A about
the character of the state. An official role for Islamic law in the state is perceived
by the latter as a tool for northern domination. In September 1983 when Nimeiri
introduced Sharia law, his regime used it to
terrorise and humiliate his opponents with indefinite detention, public floggings, amputation and death penalty for ‘heretics’. Nimeiri
used the Sharia
law to justify the execution of Mahmoud Mohammed
Taha who was regarded by many as a saintly man. The role of the
Islamic law in the state has been the most challenging issue in other Muslim countries
as well. Thus the most passionate debates on this issue took place in the Constituent Assemblies
of Pakistan where the question of the adoption of the country’s constitution
arose. [See the Reports of the Constituent Assemblies of Pakistan
(1948-1956).] In the end the only Islamic provisions that appeared in the Constitution of 1956
provided (a) that the President of Pakistan was to be a Muslim and (b) that
the Islamic principles ought to govern the lives of the Muslims – a mere exhortation
and no more (Articles 24 and 32 of
the Constitution of 1956).
In Sudan several attempts have been made from time to time to resolve this
question.
[A] One approach is based on the works of the late Mahmoud Mohammed Taha. His main work is entitled “Ar Risallah Athaniya
Al-Islamiah” (Second Message of Islam). His works draw a distinction between the sources
of Islamic law (mainly the Holy Koran) and the system of law that was developed
from those sources afterwards. It argued that the latter was based on aspects
of the Koran and Sunna (the teachings and practices of the
Islam’s holy prophet Muhammad (Peace and Blessings of God be upon him)) particularly
appropriate to the specific social and political needs of the Middle
East in the eighth and ninth centuries. It was therefore “based”, so the argument went, “on the
prevailing institutions and norms of that particular time and place which had no
conception of constitutionalism and the rule of law in the modern sense of these
terms.” By basing their governmental system on the fundamental principles of justice, equality
and liberty contained in other parts of the Koran and Sunna,
the Muslims can now develop a modern constitutional order which reconciles
the aspirations of the Muslims to be governed in accordance with Islam
with the rights of all citizens”
It is submitted that this approach accepts some Islamic laws and rejects
others as being incompatible with modern ideas. It
also rejects the established way of interpreting Sharia.
This author is unable to endorse and support this approach as authentic as
being Islamic.
[B] Another approach is that of Dr Peter Nyot
Kok. Nyot Kok was the chairman of the
South Sudan Law Society. He suggested in 1991 that a general principle of political and legal coexistence could be derived from a device
used in the Criminal Bill of 1988. This was introduced
by al-Turabi, Attorney-General of the National Islamic
Front (NIF), founded by Muslim Brotherhood leaders (in particular Hassan al Turabi who as Nimeiri’s Attorney-General played a key role in introducing Sharia
in September 1983 thereby starting the current civil war. Thus it was said that a Muslim in the south would have the
choice between a huduud penalty (Islamic penalty)
and a non-huduud one.
It is submitted that this approach adopts a partial and regional application
of Islamic law. It is questionable as to whether it is an appropriate Islamic
approach. Depending on where a Muslim happens to live the application of the Sharia law would be a matter of choice for him. In one part
of the country he would have no choice in the matter while in another part of the country he could accept or reject it. This author would find such an approach unacceptable
as being Islamic.
The Fazal
Approach to the Question of the Role of the Sharia
This author’s approach to the question is as follows. It is submitted
that the Sharia law ought to apply to all Muslims
throughout the territories of the proposed federation of Sudan irrespective
of whether they live in the north or in the south. All the courts, tribunals, public authorities
and statutory bodies will administer the Islamic laws to the Muslims. However, the Sharia
law will not apply to the non-Muslims, irrespective of the province in which
they live – whether in the south or the north.
The theological justification for this application of the Sharia to Muslims only and its non-application to non-Muslims
is provided by the Holy Koran, the Muslim Holy Book. Thus, Chapter 109 (v. 2-6) of the Holy Koran
directs Muslims to say to non-Muslims,
“2. I worship not that which you worship.”
“3. Nor will you worship that which I worship.”
“4. And I shall not worship that which you are worshipping.”
“5. Nor will you worship that which I worship.”
“6. To you be your religion and to me my religion.”
It is anticipated that there will be freedom of movement throughout
the territories of the federation of Sudan. As a result, Muslims will be living in the south
and non-Muslim will be living in the north, including the federal capital
Khartoum. The question
of application of the Sharia to a person will be
determined not by his choice (as recommended by Nyot
Kok) but by whether he or she is a Muslim or non-Muslim,
as provided by the proposed constitutional settlement.
The areas of law governed by the Sharia are
as follows:
[A] Civil law: Marriage, divorce, custody of children, parentage and
legitimacy, guardianship, inheritance, wills, gifts,
trusts and the administration of estates. (Asaf
A A Fyzee, Outlines of Muhammedan Law (OUP 2002); Jamal J Nasir,
The Islamic Law of Personal Status (Graham &
Trotman, 1990).
[B] Criminal Law: homicide and law of equality (Quasas),
adultery, defamation, treason and conspiracy, robbery, an intoxicant, apostasy,
desertion from the battlefield. (Abdur Rahman, I.
Doi, Shariah: The Islamic Law (Ta-ha
Publishers, London 1984.)
[C] Commercial Law: Contract, partnership, agency, guarantees, hire
including consumer credit (Abdur Rahman, I. Doi, Shariah:
The Islamic Law, chapters 20 & 21).
What has been labelled in this article as the Fazal
approach (i.e. the application of Sharia law to
Muslims only) was adopted in the Indian Sub-continent under British rule as
far as civil law, as stated above, was concerned.
There Muslim law applied to Muslims only and Hindu law applied exclusively
to Hindus in the sphere of civil law. The system has been continued in India, Pakistan
and Bangladesh (formerly East Pakistan) after the independence in 1947.
Where one party to the same legal proceedings is Muslim and another
non-Muslim, this approach might present a problem. As for instance, where the rules of evidence
and procedure e.g. those relating to competence, compellability and reliability
of witnesses are different, the question of whether Sharia
or different laws should apply will arise.
The Fazal approach will dictate that Sharia should apply to the party/parties who are Muslim and
a different rule should apply to the party/parties who are non-Muslim. In such a case, it is submitted that the solution
should be as follows. The Islamic and
non-Islamic rules should apply to different parties (where both the rules
are identical the case should present no problems), the former to the Muslim
party and the latter to the non-Muslim party. However, the court will have an overriding duty
to administer justice fairly and equitably, both under Islamic law and under
the proposed federal constitution. Therefore,
judicial discretion will play a part in the eventual decision in the case
between the parties. Precedents of case law are likely to develop so as to
formulate the rules governing the exercise of judicial discretion. As a result, the judicial discretion is likely
to be structured by rules.
The essence of Islamic jurisprudence is JUSTICE and FAIRNESS. This might provide additional grounds for judicial
review of legislation and governmental actions. That would not be discriminatory as between
Muslims and non-Muslims. Instead it
might enrich the jurisprudence of the laws and rules across the board. Thus the High Court and the Supreme Court of
Pakistan have injected into the substantive law of judicial review of legislative
and governmental actions ‘something
in the nature of general principles of law’ (as known in French administrative
law) incorporating the concepts of impartiality, uniformity, fairness and
frankness (connoting a duty to give reasons for decisions). Islamic sources of law have furnished the jurisprudential
basis for this extended judicial review. In Pakistan
‘all three organs of the state have to act in accordance with the provisions
of the Constitution, keeping in view the Injunctions of Islam as set out in
the Holy Koran and Sunnah’. (M A Fazal,
Judicial Control etc. p. 152.) Certain
legal consequences have followed from such an approach. [A] Justiciability. The sphere of non-justiciability
seems to be diminishing. [B] Judicial review of legislation has expanded.
[C] The exercise of statutory power has to pass the test of Islamic jurisprudence.
[D] The ‘status’ and ‘contract’ distinction as known
in English law (public employees having no ‘status’, but only a ‘contract’
can be dismissed without a right of hearing) has been successfully challenged.
As a result, the employees of statutory corporations as well as civil
servants cannot be arbitrarily dismissed.
[E] The broad proposition that ‘where there is a right, there is a
remedy’ (as opposed to English law’s position that ‘only where there is a
remedy, there is a right’) has been founded on Islamic jurisprudence.
The reader is referred to a book of this author for a detailed discussion
on these points. [M A Fazal, Judicial Control of Administrative Action in India, Pakistan
and Bangladesh (Butterworths, 2000) pp 152-157.] This shows that the operation of Islamic law
side by side with other laws as well as judicial discretion in administering
the Sharia is likely to be a healthy development
in the proposed federation of Sudan.
However, the Fazal approach will have implications for legal education.
It will presuppose that practising lawyers, judges of the courts and tribunals
as well as other officials concerned with the administration of law are familiar
with Islamic Sharia law and non-Islamic law, which would operate side-by-side
within the proposed federation of Sudan. For this reason, the courses of law
run by the universities, colleges and professional bodies must contain in
their syllabi provisions of both Islamic and non-Islamic law. This will ensure
that lawyers, judges and administrators will be competent to administer both
systems of law to Muslims and non-Muslims.
For these reasons, the Fazal approach is
recommended to the parties to the conflict for adoption as a basis for a solution
to the question as to the role of the Sharia in
the proposed federation of Sudan.
Islamic
Finance
A specific question concerning an aspect of Islamic finance is pursued in
this section. It is relevant in the context of an Islamic state. That is:
what is Riba or usury [Riba is of two kinds (a) Riba Nasia i.e. interest charged
on money lent and (b) Riba Fadl i.e. taking of superior goods in exchange
for goods of inferior quality]. Riba is forbidden in Islam (The Holy Koran,
chapter 3, verse 130). The moot question is: what is Riba/usury? There are
two possible answers to this question. One is that any amount of money received
by the lender from the borrower as interest is Riba which is prohibited in
Islam. On this view, interest of a penny accepted by an investor from an investment
company on his investment of a million pounds will be Riba/usury and is forbidden.
The investor in such a case commits a sin. Those who support this view would
cite verses 278 and 279 in chapter 2 of the Holy Koran [stating “O you believe!
Observe your duty to Allah and give up what remains (due to you) from Riba,
if you are (in truth) believers. And if you do not, then be warned of war
(against you) from Allah and His Messenger. If you repent then you have your
capital sum (without interest). Wrong not and you shall not be wronged].
This view has serious implications for financial investments and the banking
system. The only way to avoid this prohibition and the ensuing penalty (see,
for instance, Sahih Al-Bukhari vol.3, Hadith no. 298 at pp. 168-169 stating
"The Prophet (Peace and Blessings of Allah be upon him) said 'This night
I dreamt that two men came and took me to a Holy land whence we proceeded
on till we reached a river of blood, where a man was standing and on the bank
was standing another man with stones in his hands. The man in the middle of
the river tried to come out but the other man threw a stone in his mouth and
forced him to go back to his original place. So whenever he tried to come
out, the other man would throw a stone in his mouth and force him to go back
to his former place. I asked ' Who is this man'? I was told ' The person in
the river was a Riba-eater'.") is to engage in trade (which is permissible)
and share the profit and loss of the investment in which the capital is invested.
Thus the Holy Koran states "And Allah has permitted trade and forbidden
usury" (chapter 2, verse 275).
The second view is that Riba/usury refers to excessive or exploitative amount
of interest charged on the capital lent. If the interest charged is fair and
reasonable and not excessive that is not Riba/usury. In Saudi Arabia a borrower
can borrow money from a bank. The borrowing is not free. Indeed the system
could not operate on the basis of free lending. The bank will charge an administrative
cost or a bank charge. The amount charged is not called 'interest' but it
is fair and reasonable in the circumstances of the lending transaction. Even
if this administrative cost or bank charge were called 'interest' that would
not necessarily amount to Riba/usury, so long as the amount were not excessive
or exploitative. Terminology is not important. What matters is the substance
of the transaction containing the charge. Those who support the second view
would cite verse 130 of chapter 3 of the Holy Koran stating "O you who
believe! Eat not Riba (usury) doubled and multiplied but fear Allah that you
may be successful". This verse seems to suggest that if the amount of
interest charged on the lending is double or multiple amount of the capital
lent then that is excessive/exploitative and is forbidden.
In view of the fact that there are two possible answers (as to what is Riba/usury)
the question is which of these answers is more viable in terms of Islamic
theology. It is submitted that the overall Islamic jurisprudence as contained
in the teachings of the Holy Koran and Hadith as a whole ought to determine
the issue. Social and economic justice between the rich and the poor [as demonstrated
by the requirement to pay zakat (compulsory charity) and the emphasis on voluntary
charity] is at the heart of Islamic values. Historically economic exploitation
of the poor by the rich has been a dominant feature of every society. Riba/usury
has been the chief instrument of such exploitation. Therefore it is not surprising
to see that Islam prohibits the use of Riba/usury as it enables the lender
to double, treble, quadruple and multiply the amount of capital lent by way
of charging the borrower with excessive/exploitative amounts of interest.
This indicates that the second answer to the question as to the meaning of
Riba/usury is more viable in Islamic jurisprudence.
Mines and Minerals: Oil
and Gas – A Federal or Provincial Subject?
In order to make an appropriate recommendation for the proposed federation
of Sudan on this matter, it is necessary to refer to the position in other
federations. In India, taxes
on mineral rights form part of the provincial subject (technically known as
‘State’) but the federal parliament
may impose limitations on mineral development. (Schedule VII, List II, Item
50 of the Constitution). Furthermore,
the federal parliament may legislate on any provincial subject, including
gas and oil on the ground that it is in the national interest to do so (Article
249).
In Germany this is a concurrent subject on which both the federal and the state
(technically known as ‘Land’) parliament
can exercise jurisdiction [The Constitution (‘Grundgesetz’) Article 74(1)]. Under Article
72(2) the federal parliament may exercise its concurrent jurisdiction where
there is a ‘need’ for such legislation. In
other words, the federal parliament may annex this provincial jurisdiction
to its own on the ground that there is a ‘need’ for such an action.
Article 3 states that federal legislation shall override provincial
law in all cases where the latter cannot be reconciled with the former.
Thus Article 3 contains the doctrine of federal supremacy, which is
to be found in all the leading federations, including Australia
(e.g. Section 109, the Commonwealth of Australia Constitution
Act 1900) and the USA (Article
VI of US Constitution). The relevant
principle has been variously described as ‘paramountcy’,
‘covering’, ‘occupied field’ or ‘the pre-emption and supersession doctrine’. (M A Fazal,
Federal Constitution for the United Kingdom – An Alternative to Devolution,
pp. 39-40.)
The position with regard to mines and minerals in Canada is
as follows: “Mineral rights vested in the Crown in the right of Canada including
those situated in [federally administered] territories and off-shore, underlying
Canada’s continental margins, as well as those underlying certain federally
owned lands within the provinces.”
“The Supreme Court of Canada in its opinion of November 1967 stated
that between Canada and the province of British Columbia, Canada has proprietary
rights in, and legislative jurisdiction over ‘lands including the mineral
and other natural resources of the sea bed and subsoil seaward from the ordinary
low water mark on the coast of the mainland and the several islands of British
Columbia outside the harbours, bays estuaries, and other similar inland waters
to the outer limit of the territorial sea of Canada, as defined in the Territorial
Sea and Fishing Zones Act’. The Court
also stated that the federal government has legislative jurisdiction ‘in respect
of the mineral and other natural resources of the seabed and subsoil beyond
that part of the territorial sea of Canada… to a depth of 200 metres or beyond
that limit, to where the depth of the superjacent waters admits of the exploitations of the mineral
and other natural resources of the said area’ [the Supreme Court expressed
its opinion in Reference Re Ownership
of Offshore Mineral Rights (1968) 65 DLR 353 (2d)].”
“In general all Crown mineral lands lying within the boundaries of
the seven provinces (with the exception of those within the Indian reserves,
national parks and other lands which are under the jurisdiction of the federal
government) are administered by the respective provincial governments.” (M
A Fazal, A Federal Constitution for the United Kingdom – An
Alternative to Devolution, p. 151)
This position is broadly similar to that in the United States. However, owing to a number
of provisions of the US constitution, the federal jurisdiction over oil and gas has been considerably
enhanced.
A] The Supremacy Clause of Article VI of the Constitution. It states
that the federal constitution and the laws enacted by the federal parliament
(Congress) in pursuance of the constitution “shall be the supreme law of the
land”. The Supremacy Clause invalidates
all states laws (i.e. the provincial laws) that conflict or interfere with
an act of Congress: Rose v Arkansas State Police 479 US 1 (1986). The same applies
to the federal government’s regulations promulgated pursuant to Congressional
legislation: Capital Cities Cable Inc.
v Crisp 469 US 691 (1984). This
is known as the ‘doctrine of pre-emption’. It would enable the federal government and parliament
to assume jurisdiction to the extent that is considered by them to be appropriate.
B] The Commerce Clause. Article I, Section VII, Subsection 3 of the
US Constitution provides that Congress shall have power to “regulate commerce
with foreign nations and among several states”.
Even in the absence of any pre-emptive legislation which comes under
the Supremacy clause (as mentioned above), the Commerce Clause bars state
regulation that unduly burdens interstate commerce. The Commerce Clause acts as an implied restraint
on state regulatory powers which must give way before the superior authority
of Congress to legislate on matters involving interstate commerce: United Building and Construction Trades of
Camden Council and Vicinity v Mayor and Council of Camden 465 US 208 (1984).
Thus “Mines and mills, factories and – all engaged in production rather
than commerce in the literal sense are brought within the sweep of the Commerce
Clause provided only that they exert some effect on interstate commerce” [Bernard
Schwartz, Constitutional Law (Macmillan, 1972) p 98].
Therefore the Commerce Clause provides another plank for the federal
jurisdiction over oil and gas. In recognition
of the Commerce Clause, the US Supreme Court has declared that a state (i.e.
a province) cannot make the payment of licence tax or the securing of a licence
a condition to carry on interstate commerce (e.g. to undertake exploration
of oil and marketing of it) and cannot tax the privilege of carrying on interstate
trade: Pacific Tel & Tel Co. v Tax
Comm 297 US 403 (1936). Neither states nor a sub-division thereof can
enforce any licence enactment, the effect of which is to embarrass commercial
communication between different states, or to discriminate against the products
of another state within the US or of
a foreign country. (Volume 51, American Jurisprudence, 2nd
ed (1968) p. 28).
C] The US Bill of Rights: The Equal Protection Clause (the 5th and
14th Amendment). Up to a
point, the US Supreme Court has been prepared to recognise the right of the
states (the provinces) in exploiting their own natural resources (e.g. oil
and gas) and in protecting the interests of the in-state business corporations,
even though their operations might result in some incidental burdens on interstate-commerce.
North-West Central Pipeline Corporation v State
Corporation Comm of Kansas 489 US 493 (1989). By contrast, judicial review of plainly discriminatory
state legislation and/or regulation is nearly always fatal. Indeed, the Supreme Court has stated that “if
a restriction on commerce is discriminatory, it is virtually per se invalid”: Oregon Waste Sys. Inc. v Department of Environment Quality 511 US 93, 99 (1994).
US Distribution of Jurisdiction
over Oil and Gas
The above discourse shows that in the USA the
Federal Government and the states (the provinces) have a parallel jurisdiction
over oil and gas, but that, for the reasons states above, the federal authority
on the matter has been strengthened. Considerations
of natural conservation and environmental protection have contributed to this
trend. The jurisdiction over offshore
oil and gas belongs to the federal government. The relevant federal statutes authorises the
granting of oil and gas leases on the submerged lands of the outer continental
shelf (the Outer Continental Shelf Act: 93 USC ss.
1331 et seq). The federal government exercises similar jurisdiction
over federal lands. The federal statute
(the Mineral Leasing Act of 1970) governs the issue of permits for exploration
and of leases for production for federally owned oil and gas resources.
The states (provinces) exercise similar jurisdiction over state lands.
Insofar as the right to regulate the gas and oil industry is based
upon their welfare power (technically known as the ‘police power’ in US law),
it is vested primarily in the states. Under
the view that production is essentially a mining operation, this phase of
the business cannot be governed by federal law, even though it is shipped
into interstate or foreign commerce. However,
the state operations will be subject to various constitutional provisions,
as discussed above. (See
volume 38, American Jurisprudence, 2nd ed., pp. 620-621, 725-727, 735-737
and 742-743.)
It is submitted that the distribution of jurisdiction over oil, gas
and other minerals between the federal government and the provinces in our
proposed federation of Sudan ought to follow the US model.
Civil Service
It is necessary to deal with the question of civil service under the
proposed federal structure. This issue
has its origin in the days before the independence of Sudan in
1956. Although Sudan achieved
independence without conflict, it inherited many of the current problems from
the Anglo-Egyptian Condominium. Chief
among these was the question of the status of the civil service.
The residents of the three southern provinces of Al Istiwai,
Bahr al Ghazal and Aali an Nil resented
the replacement of British administrators in the south with northern Sudanese.
Under the proposed federal constitution, each of the federating units
(to be called the ‘provinces’ under our proposal) would have its own civil
service to administer the functions assigned to the provinces.
The provincial civil service will be open only to the residents of
the respective provinces, irrespective of race, colour, religion and language. The federal civil service, including the defence
services, would however be open to the residents of all the provinces, strictly
on merits. Therefore, each provincial
civil service will comprise its own residents.
President and Prime Ministers
If the presidential system of government, as it prevails in the USA, is
adopted in Sudan, it is envisaged that the president would be the effective holder
of power in the proposed federation of Sudan at
the federal level. In this case, it
is recommended that the offices of the president and vice-president ought
to rotate between the northerners and southerners.
Thus, if the president is elected from the north for one term, the
vice-president should be elected from the south for the same term. The following term, their respective roles should
be reversed. That is to say, the president
should be from the south and the vice-president should be elected from the
north.
If the system of government adopted is one of a parliamentary system,
as exists in Britain, the prime minister would be the holder of real power at the federal
level. In such a case, it is recommended
that the offices of the prime minister and the president (the ceremonial head
of state) should alternate between the northerners and the southerners.
In other words, if the prime minister is elected from the north, the
president should be from the south for one term.
For the following term, the prime minister should be from the south
and the president from the north. The
choice for these officers to be made by parliament would, therefore, have
to be limited in the terms as indicated above.
Recommendation for the Proposed Federation of Sudan
In view of the pronounced demand of the parties to the conflict in
Sudan, viz. the demands of the southerners for the maximum of autonomy, democracy
and constitutionalism, and those of the northerners for a resolution of these
issues within the framework of one country, it is submitted that the federal
model constructed in a book of this author entitled ‘A Federal Constitution
for the United Kingdom – An Alternative to Devolution’ (Dartmouth/Ashgate 1997) be adopted as a basis for a federal solution
to this conflict.
The model seeks to provide for the maximum of autonomy for the federating
units, adequate resources for the centre as well as the provinces to meet
their constitutional functions and responsibilities, a role in foreign affairs
for the provinces, including, where appropriate, individual membership of
the United Nations and other international organisations. The proposed system contains the provisions
of ‘regional equalisation’ between the federating provinces, designed to ensure
a uniform standard of living throughout the territories of the federation,
coupled with ‘vertical’ and ‘horizontal’ fiscal equalisation between the different
levels of government.
The provisions of composition, powers and functions of the upper house
of the federal parliament are so designed as to provide a meaningful share
of power at the centre for the federating provinces. The details of these schemes are set out below.
The Upper House of the Proposed Federal/Confederal Parliament
Introductory
The strategy
behind this model for the upper house is two-fold. First, the countries constituting the proposed
federation ought to retain much of their current independence at the state
level. Secondly, they should all have
a meaningful share of power at the centre.
This objective is the guiding consideration behind the formulation
of the detailed proposals for (a) composition, (b) powers and (c) for devising
machinery for the resolution of deadlocks/disputes between the lower and the
upper houses of the confederal/federal parliament.
A federation normally comprises large and small states, the latter
being apprehensive of domination by the former.
As a consequence, the second chamber is so designed as to be able to
protect the interest of the weaker states as against the stronger states.
Composition
of the Upper House
The question
of composition involves two issues, viz. (1) distribution of seats i.e. how
many seats each of the territories comprising the federation ought to have
in the upper house of the federal parliament. (2) Representation of the territorial
units in the upper chamber. On the
first point, since some states are likely to be more populous than others,
a compromise is called for. Thus the
US model gives two seats in the Senate to each State
in the USA irrespective of population so that small states are
not swamped in a parliament elected on the basis of population. In Germany, on the other hand, the compromise formula gives
neither equal representation to states, nor is it strictly based on population.
Thus Art. 51 of the German Constitution provides,
“(1) The Bundesrat [the
upper house] consists of members of the Länder [states]
governments which appoint and recall them. Other members of such governments may act as
substitutes.”
(2) Each Land has at least three votes; Länder with more than two million inhabitants have four, Länder with more than seven million inhabitants six votes.
(3) Each Land may delegate as many members as it has
votes. The votes of each Land may be
cast only as block vote and only by members present or their substitutes.”
The effect of the Art. 51 formula might be that larger states are under-represented
(e.g. the state of North Rhine Westphalia have almost thirty times the population
of Bremen, but has only double the number of Bundesrat seats), but it provides a strong voice for the small
states or under-populated areas. Therefore,
the German model is recommended for adoption for the proposed federation.
However, weighted voting for the countries constituting the federation
(as distinct from the federating units such as the states in India) might deserve consideration.
In the European
Union the Council of Ministers is represented by the Member States on the
basis of weighted voting. Where the
Council is required to act by qualified majority voting, the votes of its
members are weighted as follows:
Belgium |
5 |
Denmark |
3 |
Germany |
10 |
Greece |
5 |
Spain |
8 |
France |
10 |
Ireland |
3 |
Italy |
10 |
Luxembourg |
2 |
Netherlands |
5 |
Austria |
4 |
Portugal |
5 |
Finland |
3 |
Sweden |
4 |
United Kingdom |
10 |
(EU Treaty,
Art 205(2))
Representation
in the European Parliament is weighted as follows:
Belgium |
25 |
Denmark |
16 |
Germany |
99 |
Greece |
25 |
Spain |
64 |
France |
87 |
Ireland |
15 |
Italy |
87 |
Luxembourg |
6 |
Netherlands |
31 |
Austria |
21 |
Portugal |
25 |
Finland |
16 |
Sweden |
22 |
United Kingdom |
87 |
(EU Treaty,
Art 190(2))
In our model,
the Council of Ministers and the European Parliament of the European Union
ought to be perceived as comparable to the upper and lower houses of the proposed
federation.
On the second
issue the territorial representation of the federating units in the upper
chamber may be achieved through either (a)
governments of the states e.g. through appointment by the state governments
as in Germany or (b) state assemblies as in India or (c) the people i.e. direct
election as in the USA or Switzerland. Election of the upper house by the
state assemblies or by the voters might make the chamber democratically accountable
but the elected members have no automatic connection with the state government
of the area they represent; nor do they provide any meaningful link between
the upper house of the federal parliament and the respective state assemblies.
We have
stated at the outset that our guiding consideration is to ensure that the
countries constituting the proposed federation must have a meaningful share
of power at the centre. This consideration dictates that we should adopt the
German model i.e. representation of state governments to constitute the upper
house. The German Parliament is the only example in the world where the upper
house is entirely composed of members of the government of the federating
states. The German Bundesrat is said “to be closest
comparator to the European Council of Ministers. There are considerable advantages
associated with such a system:[a] It creates a real
institutional link between the states and the centre…[b] It makes intergovernmental
relations transparent …[c] It genuinely binds regional and national concerns
together. Because state governments can scrutinise national policy and because they bring their own policy
concerns to the table, this fosters a better understanding between the states
and the centre and allows joint strategies to be developed. It may even result
in territorial governments being prepared to effectively ‘pool’ their powers
to legislate upwards – since they have an opportunity through the upper house
to influence national legislation” [Meg Russell Representing the Nations &
Regions in a New Upper House (1999,The Constitutional Unit , UCL,) p.13 ].
However,
we are not advocating a wholesale adoption of the practices and procedure of the German
Bundesrat (i.e. the upper house) . It has been said
that “the German Bundesrat is not a parliamentary
chamber in the usual sense of the term. It meets only once every six weeks, for a session
which generally lasts around half a day. There are no lengthy debates in plenary sessions,
with much negotiation going on in committee. Instead plenary sessions, which are generally
poorly attended, are quick and efficient events where positions negotiated
in committee are formally voted on. Meanwhile the committees themselves are
attended almost exclusively by civil servants, who deputise
for ministers” (Meg Russell, op. cit. 13-14).
We envisage
the upper house of the proposed federation to be a full scale legislative
chamber.
Powers of
the Upper House
In true
federal systems (as opposed to quasi-federal ones) the upper chamber tends
to be more powerful. Thus in the USA bills are introduced in either house but the Senate
can amend or veto any legislation including financial legislation (although
finance bills have to be introduced in the lower house). Constitutional amendments
have to be passed by a 2/3 majority in both houses. In addition the Senate
has powers to approve executive appointments, ratify treaties, declare war
etc.
In Germany the upper house has the opportunity to see and comment
on all the bills before their introduction in the lower house. Constitutional
amendments have to be passed by a 2/3 majority in both houses of the federal
parliament.
The upper
house of the federal parliament in Germany has an absolute veto on all bills affecting the jurisdiction
of the states – around 60 per cent of bills. This is because the states administer
most federal laws. One commentator has said “ The German Bundesrat is successful
at binding the states and the national parliament together because of the
particular nature of German federalism
. Whilst most policy is decided in outline at national level ,the implementation of
this policy and consideration of its detail ,goes on in the Länder (i.e. the states). The Länder
are the mechanism for implementation of government policy and thus central to decision-making.
This is reflected in their powers in the Bundesrat ,where they have an absolute veto on all bills affecting their
work –around 60 per cent of legislation. This includes most financial legislation.
The existence of two categories of legislation in Germany and the power of the Bundesrat
veto over one of them, further strengthens the institution
and the links between national and state levels. If the powers of the Bundesrat
were not so considerable ,it would not be able to
maintain the involvement of senior government ministers from the Länder.
This would not be feasible if, for example, the upper house had
only the power to delay legislation … If a chamber is to function effectively
as a territorial upper house …it must be given some genuine powers over territorial
issues [i.e. issues affecting the states] (Meg Russell, op. cit. 14)
In Germany the upper house is decisive on European matters affecting
the states in addition to its role in electing the judges of the federal Constitutional
Court and for
‘state of defence’. The above consideration ought
to be borne in mind in prescribing the powers of the upper house in our proposed
federation.
Resolution
of Disputes between the Upper and Lower Houses
In devising
an appropriate procedure/machinery to resolve disputes between the houses
of parliament we will be guided by our starting premises viz. 1. that the countries constituting the proposed federation ought
to be able to safeguard their allocated sphere of independence/ autonomy and 2. that they should have a real share of power at the centre.
The possible options for such procedure/machinery are as follows.
A. The ‘suspensive veto’
as exercised by the British House of Lords. It merely interposes a delay between the introduction
of a bill and its final passage into law. Ultimately the will of the House
of Commons which is elected on the basis of population prevails. In the context
of our proposed federal framework this will not provide the necessary checks
and balance as envisaged. Therefore this option is ruled out.
B. The endless
shuttle of bills between the two houses as experienced in Australia. This is also unsatisfactory. The process could only
end by dissolving both houses of parliament.
C. Joint
sitting of two houses of parliament. This is used in India. The objection to this device in a federal context
is that under this procedure the will of the lower house which is generally
elected on the basis of population will prevail as its members are likely
to be more numerous. Under this system the smaller states cannot possibly
safeguard their position against the more populous states.
D. Joint committee of both
houses of parliament. This procedure is used in Germany and the USA. It is thought to be more productive than other devices.
“Taking discussion off the floor of the house is likely to create a more constructive
and less confrontational atmosphere in which to negotiate” [Meg Russell, Second
Chambers: Resolving Deadlock (The Constitution Unit, UCL, 1999) p.
5 ]. However, as Meg Russell states
in the paper cited here adoption of this device calls for consideration of the following questions.
1. Who can
call the joint committee?
In Germany the request will generally come from the upper house
if they receive a bill they cannot agree with. However, the request may also
come from the lower house or government in response to an upper house veto. Whoever
requests all the parties are bound to co-operate.
The German procedure is to be recommended as it provides the opportunity to
all the parties involved to initiate the process.
2. Who are
the members of the joint committee?
In Germany the upper house is composed of the members of the
states. One member from each of the 16 states is represented on the committee.
These will be senior members of the state governments. Considering the fact
that the consent of the upper house is required to a bill where the state
jurisdiction is involved (and Bundesrat will have
a veto over such a bill) this is a satisfactory way of safeguarding the states’ interests even
at the committee stage of a bill and is therefore recommended.
3.
Ad hoc or
permanent committee
In Germany a permanent committee is set up at the start of each
parliamentary session, comprising of senior figures (as in the USA). Because it consists of senior figures its recommendations are likely to be
weighty and therefore acceptable. Being
a permanent committee its members are likely to develop trust and co-operation
(which is less likely on ad hoc committees). For this reason permanent committee
is recommended.
4. What
can the joint committee discuss?
In the USA the committee is limited to the specific clauses
of the bill which are in dispute. In Germany the committee’s remit is somewhat wider. It is restricted
only to matters which are specified in the motion to convene it. This might
permit the committee to add a new clause not previously covered by bill. The
German Constitutional Court ruled in 1986 that this was permissible but that
it was ‘close to the limit of
the legally acceptable’. Nonetheless the German procedure provides
for flexibility and is recommended.
5. How is
the joint committee decision taken?
In the USA the groups representing the two houses vote as blocks
with one vote each, agreement depending on a majority among representatives
of each house. The decision is very often a compromise between the parties.
In Germany the decision is taken by a majority of votes of committee
members. Here the decision is a compromise among the states. In the joint committee the states have one representative
each but in the upper house the states have different number of votes. The
committee has to take this fact into account.
On our approach
it is the interests of the states rather than of the parties that matter most
and consequently the decisions have to reflect a compromise among the states.
For this reason the German model is recommended.
6. Can joint
committee proposals be amended by the house?
In the USA and Germany the committees’ proposals may not be amended by either
house when they are discussed in the house, unless the committee itself recommends
otherwise. It is submitted that this
position is preferable in the interest of the integrity and status of the
committee.
7. Who has
the last word?
In Germany there are two classes of bills – (1) The upper house has a veto on bills that affect the jurisdiction
of the states. (2) On the remaining bills the lower house has the last word.
On a bill that is subject to veto by the upper house, once the committee
has been called (a committee may be called on any bill where the houses disagree
either by the lower house or by the federal government or by the upper house),
its recommendations must be accepted or else the bill dies.
In the USA all legislation must be agreed by both houses.
The recommendations of the joint committees are subject to the same
rule. Failure to
agree results in the death of the bill or in another committee being called.
It is submitted
that the German procedure of joint committee (in which each of the sixteen
states are represented by one vote) provides a far more effective voice for
the states and is recommended for adoption.
Overall
the objectives of maximum independence/autonomy for the countries joining
the federation and their having a significant share of power at the centre
are better served by the adoption of the German model for the upper house
than any other in existence. For this
reason, the German model is recommended for adoption subject to the modifications
noted above.
Machinery
and Model for the Removal of Regional Disparity
Maintenance
of integrity and unity of a federation requires measures to maintain a comparable
standard of living, employment opportunities and economic development throughout
the country. Relative backwardness
of some states compared with others tend to set in process disintegrating forces. This is why Pakistan was dismembered owing to the fact that East Pakistan was perceived to be at a disadvantage economically.
This is also recognised by the European Union where Art 158 of the Treaty
provides,
“In order to provide overall harmonious development,
the Community shall develop and pursue its actions leading to the strengthening
of its economic and social cohesion. In particular, the Community shall aim at reducing
disparities between the levels of development of the various regions and backwardness
of the least favoured regions or islands including
rural areas.”
Art. 263
has established the Committee of the Regions where the Member
States are represented as follows:
Belgium |
12 |
Denmark |
9 |
Germany |
24 |
Greece |
12 |
Spain |
21 |
France |
24 |
Ireland |
9 |
Italy |
24 |
Luxembourg |
6 |
Netherlands |
12 |
Austria |
12 |
Portugal |
12 |
Finland |
9 |
Sweden |
12 |
United Kingdom |
24 |
Art. 265
has imposed a mandatory duty on the Council of Minister and the European Commission
to consult the committee of the Regions “where the Treaty provides and in
all other cases”.
Model for
Development of Regional Parity
In his answer
to the questionnaire (q. 5.6.) issued by the Commission on Centre-State Relations
in India as to whether a special federal fund for ensuring ‘faster development
in economically backward areas relative to other developed areas of the country’
is necessary, this author suggested a model for development in the following
terms:
“I have indicated … that such a fund is clearly necessary
in the case of India. It could
be funded by taxes on petrol, gas or other forms of energy, or alternatively
on consumption of good and services. The
Finance Commission is not the appropriate body to administer such a fund which
would involve regional planning. It
has got to be the planning commission acting in collaboration with the state
governments concerned. The strategy
would be first to develop the economic infrastructure. When that is done, a balanced development –
balanced between the urban and rural sectors – would be aimed at. This would be an all-round development of the
villages involving an integration of trade, industry and agriculture coupled
with the restoration of ecological balance and afforestation
as a part of soil and environmental conservation measures. Elimination of the distinction between the town
and the villages in terms of amenities and economic activities ought to be
set as the objectives. It is submitted
that each Thana [the size of a police area in the British- ruled
Bengal] should
be taken as a unit of development. This
model roughly corresponds to, but is not identical with the commune system
in China. It is designed
to prevent drift to the cities and deprivation of rural areas.”
“The upsurge in the Third World urban population has overwhelmed resources. Sprawling slums, massive traffic jams, chronic
unemployment, breakdown of essential services etc. are causing communal tensions
(as happened in Bombay and Hydrabad in 1984).
In 1984 the population of Delhi, Karachi and Calcutta is estimated to be 7 million, 7 million and 11 million
respectively. By the year 2025, the
population projection of these cities is expected to be 20-30 million each.
The development that I am advocating here i.e. a balanced development
between the rural and urban sectors is designed to stop the drift to the towns
and avoid the urban explosion.”
[M A Fazal, A Federal Constitution for the United Kingdom – An Alternative to Devolution (1997, Dartmouth/Ashgate) pp. 256-257]
It is submitted
that appropriate machinery and model for the removal of regional disparity
is crucial to ensure the success of the proposed federation.
Equalisation in the Proposed Federation
The model
for our proposed federation is one of maximum decentralisation.
It is likely that regional disparities among its constituent units of such
a federation would be significant. As stated above, marked regional disparities
among the constituent units are fatal to the integrity of a federation. The
states will compete with each other in order to attract business and industry.
To be able to do that successfully they must have the necessary infrastructure
and be in a position to supply quality services. This calls for the incorporation
of the appropriate equalising mechanism.
The equalising principles devised to cement the unity of a federation
are of two types:
1. Regional Equalisation designed to achieve broadly
uniform economic development and uniform standard of living throughout the
territories of a federation; and
2. Fiscal Equalisation.
Article
104a (4) of the German Constitution reflects the concept of the first type
by stating that the Federation may grant the Länder
(the States) financial assistance for particularly important investments by
the Länder or communes or association of communes, provided that
such investments are necessary to avert a disturbance of the overall economic
equilibrium or to equalise differences of economic
capacities within the federal territory or to promote economic growth.
Regional
Equalisation.
The principles
of regional equalisation are embodied in the provisions
of the Treaty of the European Union. Thus Articles 2 and 3 of the Treaty state
that one of its tasks is to "promote throughout the Community a harmonious,
balanced and sustainable development of economic activities, a high level
of employment and of social cohesion, […] the raising of the standard of living
and quality of life, and economic and social cohesion and solidarity among
Member States". Title XVII of the Treaty headed: Economic and Social
Cohesion develops this concept further. Thus Article 158 states that "[i]n
order to promote its overall harmonious development, the Community shall develop
and pursue its actions leading to the strengthening of its economic and social
cohesion. In particular, the Community shall aim at reducing disparities between
the levels of development of the various regions and the backwardness of the
least favoured regions or islands, including the rural areas".
In addition
to permitting Member states of the Union to grant
aids to achieve regional parity under Article 87 [see for instance, Preussent Elektra v. Schleswag (2001)
All E.R. (EC) 330 containing a ruling of the European Court of Justice on
the interpretation of Article 87] the Treaty provides by Article 159.
“Member States shall conduct their economic policies
and shall coordinate them in such a way as, in addition, to attain the objectives
set out in 158. The formulation and implementation of the Community's policies
and actions and the implementation of the internal market shall take into
account the objectives set out in Article 158 and shall contribute to their
achievement. The Community shall also support the achievement of these objectives
by the action it takes through the Structural Funds (European Agricultural
Guidance and Guarantee Fund, Guidance Section; European Social Fund; European
Regional Development Fund), the European Investment Bank and the other existing
financial instruments.”
Article
160 states that "[t]he European Regional Development Fund is intended
to help redress the main regional imbalances in the Community through participation
in the development and structural adjustment of regions whose development
is lagging behind and in the conversion of declining industrial regions”.
Article
161 authorised the setting up of a Cohesion Fund
to provide a financial contribution to projects in the fields of environment
and trans-European networks in the area of transport infrastructure.
Therefore
the measures to deal with regional disparities are undertaken at two levels:
1. The EU financial assistance provided via the Structural Funds and 2. Regional
aids granted at national levels by the national governments in conformity
with the law of the European Union. The reform of the Structural Funds in
1988 gave rise to four Funds: the European Regional Development Fund ( ERDT)
to finance infrastructure, productive investment to create jobs, local development
projects and assistance to small and medium-sized firms, the European Social
Fund (ESF), to help the workforce adapt to changes in the labour
market and help the unemployed and other disadvantaged groups to get back
to work, in particular by funding training and recruitment schemes, the European
Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund (EAGGF) to finance rural development
measures and assistance to farmers, mainly in regions whose development is
lagging behind, but also under the common agricultural policy of the EU and
the Financial Instrument for Fisheries Guidance (FIFG) to finance structural
reform in the fisheries sector. Further EU assistance is provided by other
institutions such as the European Investment Bank.
The Structural
Funds are used to provide the EU financial assistance to regions and groups
in need of assistance. They are based on the following seven objectives set
out in the "Framework" Regulation 2052/88 [substantially amended
by Regulation 2081/93 and by the decision of the Council of the European Union
of 1 January 1995 adjusting instruments concerning the accession of the new
Member States to the EU: (1995) O.J. L1/1. The latter added Objective No.6]:
Objective
1 - To assist regions whose development is lagging behind.
Objective
2 - to revitalise regions affected by serious industrial
decline,
Objective
3 - to combat long term un-employment,
Objective
4 - to integrate young people in the labour,
Objective
5a - to adjust agricultural schemes,
Objective
5b - to develop rural areas,
Objective 6 - to promote the development and structural
adjustment of regions with an extremely low population density.
As a result
of the EU Regional Equalisation Policy, average
per capita income in the three least prosperous countries (Greece, Portugal and Spain) increased from 68% of the Community average to 79%
in 1999.
Therefore
I would recommend the incorporation of the EU objectives into the laws and
the constitution of the proposed federation with the emphasis on the overall
uniform economic development of its constituent units and the aim of realising uniform standard of living throughout all the territories.
Fiscal Equalisation
The principle
of fiscal equalisation seeks to deal with two types
of fiscal imbalances (i.e. the gap between the revenue capacity and the expenditure
responsibility): 1. Vertical Fiscal Imbalance and 2. Horizontal Fiscal Imbalance. Vertical fiscal imbalance is said
to arise where the revenue capacity of a level of government cannot match
its expenditure responsibilities. Generally vertical fiscal imbalance is in
favour of the federal government and against the state or
regional government (as in Australia). Indeed it is unwise and can be dangerous to invest
the centre with too many constitutional responsibilities and too few taxes
and resources. This is what was done in Germany under the Weimar Constitution with disastrous consequences.
The federal government was forced to cover its budget deficit by issuing debts
resulting in hyper-inflation. That in turn caused the rise of the Third Reich
which brought about the Second World War [Carsten
Hefeker," The Agony of Central Power: Fiscal
Federalism in the German Reich" (2001) 5 European Review of Economic
History 119-142]. It is equally undesirable to endow regional/state governments
with power to issue debt without appropriate constitutional safeguards.
Horizontal
fiscal imbalance arises among the constituent units of a federation because
of (a) differences in the costs of providing equivalent services in the individual
states and (b) differences in their capacities to raise their own-source revenues.
The statement
of the principle of fiscal equalisation adopted
by the Commonwealth Grants Commission in Australia [an independent body established
in 1933 that advises the federal government on (i)
fiscal equalisation and (ii) distribution of funds
for programme to assist the indigenous population
- Commonwealth Grants Commission -Annual Report : 2000-01, p.7 ] is that,
"State
governments should receive funding from the Commonwealth (i.e. the Federation)
such that if each made the same effort to raise revenue from its own sources
and operated at the same level of efficiency, each would have the capacity
to provide services at the same standard" [Commonwealth Grants Commission,
Report on General Grants Relativities 1999, Volume 1, Main Report, p.4].
The principle
is intended to ensure that each State Government has the financial capacity
to provide the same level of service to its residents. In using the principle
to calculate relativities the Commission takes into account differences among
the States in (i) their per capita capacities to
raise revenues; (ii) the per capita amount they would spend if they were to
provide the average level of services; and (iii) their per capita receipts
of SPPs [ Specific Purpose
Payments-40% of the total federal transfers to the States in 2001: Commonwealth
Grants Commission : Report on State Revenue Sharing Relativities: 2002 Update,
p.5].
The methods
used to calculate these differences involve (1) the preparation of the FINANCIAL
STANDARDS (the per capita average of total State expenditure or revenue for
each function), (2) the STANDARD BUDGET (the collection of all the expenditure
and revenue categories and then calculating (i)
for each State service, the per capita expenditure each State would require
if it were to provide the average level of service and (ii) for each source
of State revenue, the per capita revenue each State would raise if it applied
the Australian average revenue raising effort to its revenue base; (3) EXPENDITURE
ASSESSMENT methods (to adjust the standard expenditures to allow for influences
beyond the control of individual States that require a State to spend more
or less per capita than others to provide the average standard of service
to arrive at the state's cost of service provision. The influences thus recognised would relate to characteristics of State population
or physical and economic environment because these would influence the State's
costs in providing services.) (4) REVENUE ASSESSMENT methods (to take account
of the influences beyond a State's control that would result in it raising
more (or less) revenue per capita than other States if it applied Australian
average rates of tax to its tax bases. Tax bases are generally measured using
the value of transactions in each State that would be taxed under the average
tax policy).
A State's
per capita requirement for a share of the pool of funds available for distribution
in each assessment year is then calculated as follows:
- An equal per capita share
of the pool plus adjustments for;
- the effect of assessed
influences on demand for and cost of providing services - expenditure needs;
- the effect of assessed
influences on revenue capacities - revenue needs;
- the specific purpose
payments (SPPs) it has available to fund its expenditure
requirements
(5) CALCULATION
OF PER CAPITA RELATIVITIES i.e. the measures of relative needs used to distribute
the GST (Goods and Services Tax) and HCG (Health Care Grants). The final phase
of the process is to use the assessments for the past five years to calculate
per capita relativities to apply in the future. Each State's relativity is
the average of its per capita requirements for a share of the pool in each
of the five past years.
In 2001-02,
about $2150 million (equivalent to 6% of the total GST/HCG pool and budget
balancing assistance) was required to bring the financial capacities of those
States with below average capacities up to the average (to meet their aggregate
needs) [Commonwealth Grants Commission: Report on State Revenue Sharing Relativities
2002 Update, pp.4 - 7].
On 1 July 2000 major reforms reflecting the Inter-governmental Agreement
on the reform of the Commonwealth-State Relations (IGA 1999) came into force:
A New Tax System (Commonwealth-State Financial Arrangements) Act 1999. Under
this provision the Commonwealth introduced a broad-based consumption tax called
the Goods and Services Tax (GST). The 1999 Agreement specifies that the distribution
of the GST revenue among the States will be based on horizontal equalisation
principles - per capita relativities recommended by the Commonwealth Grant
Commission as explained above. It also commits the Commonwealth to provide
additional assistance (known as ' budget balancing assistance') during the
transitional years prior to the abolition of some State taxes and imposition
of additional expenditure responsibilities on the States (to ensure that no
State will be worse off than it would have been, had the tax reforms not been
implemented).
Horizontal Equalisation
The States'
revenue capacity can vary significantly, thereby affecting their capacity
to provide services of the national average. The principle of horizontal equalisation
seeks to remedy this defect. Thus Mitchell Sharp, the federal finance minister
of Canada said in 1966
"The
fiscal arrangements should, through a system of equalisation
grants, enable each province to provide an adequate level of public services
without resort to rates of taxation substantially higher than those of other
provinces" [ Canada, Federal-Provincial Tax Structure Committee, Proceedings
of a meeting held in Ottawa, September 14-15,1966 (Ottawa, Queen's Printer,1966), 14].
The above
statement was explained as follows: It would provide that any province in
which average provincial tax rates (not its own tax rates) would yield less
revenue per capita than the yield in Canada as a whole would be entitled to an equalisation payment. However, changes in energy supplies
and values in the 1970s and 1980s resulted in the sudden shift in the relative
positions of provinces in Canada that produced oil and provinces that consumed it.
This had effect on the equalisation formula. The
automatic response of the equalisation formula to
the increases in provincial oil revenues was to increase the entitlements
of the recipient provinces. Thus the federal government faced the prospect
that one of its major spending programmes would
escalate uncontrollably [David B.Perry, Financing
the Canadian Federation, 1867 to 1995: Setting the Stage for Change (Canadian
Tax Foundation, 1997),,pp.124 and 133.]. This called
for a review of the equalisation formula in the
light of developments.
In Australia the Intergovernmental Agreement (signed on 1 July 1999) provides that the interstate distribution of the
GST will be based on per capita relativities determined by the Commonwealth
Grants Commission. At the first meeting of the Ministerial Council for Commonwealth-State
Financial Relations (established under the IGA 1999) held on 30 March
2001, New South Wales and Victoria complained that they received much less than equal
per capita share of funding under the HFE (Horizontal Fiscal Equalisation) relativities determined by the CGC. The problem
is that while vertical imbalance is reduced significantly (in the absence
of equalisation arrangements) by equal per capita
payments to the States or payments in proportion to the tax collected in each
State, horizontal equalisation is achieved best
by payments or grants that take accounts of differences in costs of providing
services and revenue capacities. However, payments or grants to the States
on the latter basis would result in unequal per capita amounts. Nonetheless
formula-based approaches implemented by an independent institution are preferable
to political negotiations as mechanism for the equalisation
process.
Elaborate
equalisation mechanism exists also in the German
federal system. In view of the fact that income taxes are shared between the
federal and state governments in fixed proportion (50% going to the federation
and 50% to the states) the vertical fiscal balance is achieved in Germany mainly by varying the V.A.T. This is done by federal
legislation which requires the consent of the Bundesrat
(the upper house of the German Parliament: Article 106 of the Constitution).
Vertical equalisation was last revised in 1992 when
the Eastern states were included in intergovernmental fiscal arrangements
(taking effect in 1996). As a result, the states' shares of the V.A.T. have
increased reflecting the need of the Eastern states to reach parity with their
Western counterparts. At present the federal share of the V.A.T. stands at
50.5 percent.
Horizontal
fiscal balance is achieved in three steps.
1. The regional
apportionment of the V.A.T. Three quarters of the states' shares are apportioned
on the basis of population. Another quarter is reserved for the states considered
to be "financially weak". They receive supplementary transfers from
the V.A.T. to bring their fiscal potential to per capita up to 92 percent
of the average.
2. An interregional
redistribution scheme. The 'rich' states compensate the 'poor' states through
financial transfers. This is also done on the basis of federal legislation
which requires the consent of the Bundesrat, "due
account being taken of the financial capacity" (i.e. the taxable capacity)
of the states and not of the specific burdens (Article 107(2) of the German
Constitution (Grundgesetz). The German Constitutional Court in its ruling of 11 November 1999 emphasised that the Constitution
requires the federal Parliament to take measures to equalise the differences in the financial capacity of the
states. This refers to actual financial resources and not to a relationship
between revenue and specific expenditure needs. It is different from the equalisation practices of Australia. The interstate equalising
transfer is unique to Germany and does not exist anywhere in the Commonwealth or
elsewhere.
3. Supplementary
Grants. Thus Article 107(2) of the German Constitution states that the above
mentioned federal statute may also provide for grants to be made by the Federation
from federal funds to financially weak Länder in
order to complement the coverage of their general financial requirements.
Such transfers have been widely used after unification of Germany. In particular "gap filling" grants have
been introduced that guarantee at least 99.5 percent of the average fiscal
capacity for all states. Furthermore, nine states out of sixteen receive federal
grants to relieve the costs of "political management" and the new
Eastern states (as well as some Western counterparts) receive federal grants
in compensation for "special burdens" [Paul Bernd Spahn," The German Constitutional Court takes on the
principle of 'solidarity' ( Federations, vol.1, number 1, March 2001)].
The German
equalisation system seeks to achieve what is known
in Europe as "interregional solidarity". However,
recently it has come under criticism from some of the rich states. Thus in
the above mentioned case of 1999 three Southern states (Baden-Wurttemberg,
Bavaria and Hessen) mounted a challenge before the
Federal Constitutional Court against the system of intergovernmental fiscal
arrangements. They complained that it redistributes wealth to an excessive
degree and creates negative incentives. In fact they wanted to replace it
with 'competitive federalism'. Up to a point the challenge succeeded. The
Court was particularly critical of the federal equalising
grants. At present these have a strong equalising
effect (99.5% of the state average for all states). As a result the federal
government will have to reduce the number of grants as well as their magnitude.
On horizontal
equalisation according to the Court, the Constitution
mandates that population be adopted as the sole criterion for distributing
resources among the states as opposed to an approach based on needs as in
Australia. I have some sympathy with this approach of the Federal Constitutional Court. It is much more difficult to establish objective
"needs criteria" than population as a criterion even among entities
with comparable responsibilities at sub-national levels, let alone those between
governments at national and sub-national levels where there may not always
be comparable responsibilities. As for instance, defence
is a major national responsibility but it is absent at sub-national levels.
On vertical
equalisation the Court ruled that the Constitution
demands a definition of 'necessary expenditures' at each level of government
and 'a fair compensation' among jurisdictions on the basis of objective statistical
data and medium term planning. The Court criticised the existing practice of weighting population as
a method to express burdens in the case of the city states. The Court called
for a scientific procedure of balancing, based on accurate data. However,
the federal government wants to retain the weighting in the case of the city
states (such as Berlin). There are some positive elements in the ruling
of the Court. However, it will require a fundamental review of the existing
German equalisation law.
Meanwhile
political pressures are also building up for the introduction of competitive
rather than co-financing federalism in Germany. Under the Solidarity Pact 11 signed on 23 June 2001 between the Federation and the States the financial
support for East German Länder will end in 2019.
Moreover, the reform of the German system of co-financing as a whole has been
scheduled for 2004, the year of the next European Intergovernmental Conference
which will decide upon a delimitation of powers within the European Union.
Within the European legal framework Länder and regions
have become competitors in attracting investments. The national state such
Germany is losing its capacity to protect those Länder which are less successful. Therefore, the progress
of European integration is pushing federal reform in Germany forward.
However,
the system of fiscal equalisation has its rationale.
Its rationality lies in the maintenance of uniformity of living conditions
and the provision of comparable public services throughout the territories
of the federation. Any departure from the equalisation
principle will carry with it the risk of disturbing the social cohesion and
solidarity and a threat to the integrity of the country. Therefore the decision-makers
would be well-advised to bear this warning in mind.
India
There are
two financial institutions in India which were designed primarily to deal with the issue
of vertical fiscal imbalance between the centre (technically known as the
Union) and the States, and, to a lesser extent, with that
of the horizontal fiscal imbalance. The first is the quinquennial
Finance Commission set up under the Constitution (Article 280). The task of
the Finance Commission is to make recommendations to the Union Government
on the following: (1) the distribution of the net proceeds of the specified
taxes (income tax, federal excise tax etc.) between the Union and the States;
(2) the principles governing the Union grants-in-aid to the various States
(the resource poor States); (3) the transfer to the States needed to supplement
the resources of the Panchayats (local rural self-government
institutions) and the Municipalities (urban local self-government institutions).
Up to 1978 the two criteria used as the basis of distribution were the contribution
of each State to revenues (between 10 and 20 percent) and population (80 and
90 percent). Since then two further criteria have been added. These are the
per capita income of each State (adopted in 1978) and a complex of backwardness
including population of scheduled castes and tribes and the number of agricultural
labourers (introduced in 1989). At the time of the
Tenth Finance Commission covering the period 1995-2000 formula for distribution
of the States' share of income taxes were as follows: 20% according to population,
60% on the basis of per capita income, 5% in relation to economic and rural
infrastructure needs and 10% in relation to tax effort. Somewhat similar complex
formula was also prescribed for distribution of the States' share of the federal
excise duties. Thus population as the dominant criterion for distribution
of resources has been somewhat downgraded.
Another
financial institution is the Planning Commission, an agency of the federal
government which recommends assistance to the States by way of grants and
loans in support of various schemes coming under the Five Year Plan Programmes for poverty alleviation, employment generation
and specific development projects. The Planning Commission acts on criteria
such as 'special category States' (all the seven States in the Northeast), non-special
category States, population, poor per capital income of States, distance
factors and fiscal performance (tax effort, fiscal management, fulfilment of national objectives and special problems). These
two financial institutions operating independently of each other are said
to have undermined the overall coherence of equalisation
efforts in India [Bhattacharyya, "Federalism, Decentralisation
and State-Building in India: Aspects of Centre-State Fiscal Relations"
in R Bird and T Stauffer, eds. Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in Fragmented
Societies (Bale, Helbing and Lichtenbahn,
2001) pp.247-317].
Neither
regional equalisation, nor the principle of horizontal
fiscal equalisation has played a major part in the
programme and activities of the Indian Finance Commission
and the Planning Commission.
United Kingdom
There is
no formal system of explicit equalisation in the
United Kingdom either of resources or of needs of the type available
in Australia and Germany. However, a formula-driven pattern of resource distribution
appeared with the emergence of the administrative territorial division of
the United
Kingdom. It first
appeared in 1888 when Sir George Goschen applied
a formula (which came to be known as Goschen Formula)
to Scotland. It became necessary after Scotland had acquired a territorial administration with the
creation of the Scottish Office in 1885. The Scottish Office had the responsibility
to distribute central government grant to local authorities in Scotland. The formula was extended to Ireland in 1888. Wales was at that time deemed to be part of England but its administration was transferred to the Wales
Office in 1964.
The Goschen Formula decreed that proceeds of the wheel tax, horse
tax and half the revenue from probate should be allocated to England, Scotland and Ireland in the ratios 80, 11 and 9 respectively. This formula
was not based on population, nor on needs but on
the contribution each country made to probate duty revenues. It was not an
equalising formula but simply a device to recycle some taxes
back to the territory where they were collected. The formula continued to
operate till 1958 when it was abandoned. Thereafter funding for the Scottish,
Welsh and Northern Ireland Offices became the subject of annual negotiation
between the three territorial Secretaries and the Treasury at Westminster.
The practice
continued until 1978 when Barnett Formula was introduced in the anticipation
of Scottish devolution. Notwithstanding the fact that devolution did not materialise
at the time it has continued since then [McCrone,
G. (1999) 'Scotland's Public Finances from Goschen
to Barnett' (Fraser of Allander Institute Quarterly
Economic Commentary, vol.24. No.2)]. The Barnett Formula operates only on
increments, not on the base, allocating to each devolved territory a population
based percentage of the increase in comparable expenditure in England. Thus
for any spending programme, where there is a territorial
responsibility such as education, any increase to English budget results in
an automatic increase to Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland's budgets. For
every £1 per head extra spent on England, £1 per head extra should also go to each of the
devolved territories. The population of each devolved territory is expressed
as a fraction of England's population and not as a fraction of total UK population. It does not affect all public spending
in the devolved territories. For example, in 1998-99, £25.7bn was identified
by the Treasury as the total sum spent in Scotland. Of this only £15.6bn was in the block of spending
controlled by the Scottish Executive. Most of the remaining £10.1bn was social
security spending which comes directly from the central government. The Barnet
Formula operates only on the devolved subjects and not on subjects reserved
to Westminster. Even within the Scottish Executive budget about
14% of spending budget is not covered by the Barnett Formula. This is mainly
on agriculture and is determined by the EU decisions. Neither does the Barnett
Formula determine the overall levels of spending in Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland. It only determines the changes made to the overall
spending totals. If there is no increase in the English spending programme, the devolved territories receive no increase. If
there is a reduction, the devolved territories also have their spending reduced
[Twigger, R. (1998) The Barnett Formula, House of
Commons Library Research Paper 98/8]. The Barnett Formula is not based on
any assessment of needs for public spending but on population. In fact both
the assessment of needs and basing spending programmes
on it are not easy. For instance, the British Treasury conducted a study in
1976-78 in anticipation of devolution in Scotland and then discovered that the figures of actual spending
in Scotland and Northern Ireland were considerably higher than those based on needs.
Implementation of the needs-based figures would have involved significant
cuts in the spending programmes for Scotland and Northern Ireland. Any such cuts could have provoked a political reaction
from those territories. For this reason the needs-based figures were not implemented.
The Barnett Formula seems to be unique in the developed world. There is no
country other than the UK that allocates resources at a sub-national level
using a formula based on changes rather than levels of spending in relation
to assessed need [David Bell and Alex Christie, "Finance - The Barnett
Formula: No Body's Child ?" in Alan Trench (ed) The State of the Nations
2001 (The Constitution Unit, ULC (2001) p. 139)]. Therefore we might conclude
by saying that the Barnett Formula does not offer any lesson for a solution
to the questions of (a) regional equalisation, or
of (b) horizontal fiscal imbalance in the broad sense. It is of limited value
as a prescription for bringing about uniform standard of living throughout
the territories of the proposed federation.
Equalisation Machinery
The question
of status and standing of the machinery making the equalisation
decisions is of utmost importance to its success. In most Commonwealth federations
the actual determination of financial equalisation
is made by the federal government but it is based on the recommendations of
an expert commission as in Australia, India and South Africa or upon an intergovernmental council as in Pakistan and Malaysia. In all these cases the recommending expert institution
is an advisory body. The extent to which its recommendations are accepted
by the federal government has varied between these countries. In Australia
and India the advice of the expert body on equalisation
has invariably been accepted by the decision-making body while in South Africa
the federal government has emphasised that the expert
body (the Financial and Fiscal Commission set up under ss.
220 and 221 of the Constitution) is merely an advisory body and that it is
the federal Minister and Department of Finance that exercise the real decision-making
power. Furthermore, this is done overtly [Watts, R L, Comparing Federal Systems (1999, 2nd ed., Montreal and Kingston: McGill -Queen's University Press)]. It is thought
that the success of fiscal equalisation in Australia
is due to the fact that the Commonwealth Grants Commission is de facto, if
not de jure the decision-making body on the matter.
I have addressed
myself to this issue in the following terms:
"The
need for such a body in a federal system arises from the fact that the federal
government being itself an interested party could not be made the arbiter
over allocation of resources between the Centre and the Regions. To ensure
the autonomy of the Regions an independent body is called for. This raises
the question as to the nature of the body. Should it consist of the negotiating
parties or should it be an impartial body; should it be a permanent body or
should it be an ad hoc body set up periodically; should it act in an advisory
capacity or should it be an adjudicatory body with power to make binding decisions?
If permanent, should it have a specialist staff and a permanent secretariat?
Should it be able to act by a majority decision or need it follow the rule
of unanimity?"
"The
inter-governmental financial institution proposed has a major role to play
in our federal scheme. It would periodically review the tax-sharing arrangement
between the Centre and the Regions and consider its adjustments, allocate
shares of taxes between the two, allocate the shares of regional taxes among
the states, decide on applications for borrowing by the states and administer
an ambitious programme for equalisation
[…] to remove regional disparities between the states involving billions of
pounds. It would have power to take economic decisions of immense importance,
power of conciliation and adjudication over conflicting claims and authority
to offer economic advice to governments at the central and regional levels.
To be effective, such a body has to be impartial standing apart from and above
all the interested parties. The atmosphere in the meeting of the bargaining
body is inconsistent with the functions contemplated in this proposal. The
atmosphere of a bargaining meeting is dominated by political stress and strain,
groupings and alliances, the strongest tending to have the last word. The
experience of the Australian Grants' Commission shows that impartiality and
independence are essential to earn public confidence which is sine qua non
for its success. From this it follows that the composition of the body cannot
be entrusted to one of the interested parties. Following the precedent of
S.32 of the Government of Ireland Act 1920 the Joint Exchequer Board of the
United Kingdom federal system should consist of a member nominated by each
federating unit, one member nominated by the federal government and the chairman
appointed by the Monarch not on the basis of ministerial advice of the federal
government but having regard to his expertise in Treasury affairs, impartiality
(as between different governments) and independent judgment. Such a body ought
to be constituted on a permanent basis. A permanent body will have the advantage
of gaining expertise and consistency which an ad hoc body will lack. The drawback
from these bodies suffered in most of the new federations (by contrast with
the Australian Grants' Commission) was the lack of continuity, each body being
appointed afresh at the time of each review. An ad hoc body is appropriate
for functions of an ad hoc nature, but not for the nature of functions envisaged
in this proposal for the Joint Exchequer Board. It follows that the Joint
Exchequer Board ought to have the power to make decisions of a binding nature
and not of advisory nature. The foundation of this proposal is the division
of powers and functions between the Centre and the Regions with the Joint
Exchequer Board acting as a third party allocating resources and adjudicating
between them. If this body were to act in an advisory capacity only and the
decision-making powers were to belong to the Centre the system would cease
to be federal".
"S.
32(5) of the Government of Ireland Act 1920 empowered the Joint Exchequer
Board to act by majority decision. It is submitted that the rule of majority
decision is a sound one . If the rule of unanimity
were to apply and the members could exercise a veto on decisions of the Joint
Exchequer Board on which would depend the budgets of the federal and state
governments the whole system would become unworkable. However, it is extremely
vital that the Chairman of the Board be impartial….[T]o make the Joint Exchequer
Board less political and more independent the costs of the Board (including
salaries of the members and staff) should be charged on the federal Consolidated
Fund. The Constitution will ensure that these could be increased but not reduced
by the federal parliament." [M A Fazal,
A Federal Constitution for the United Kingdom - An Alternative to Devolution (1997) pp. 107-109].
The case
for an independent and impartial decision-making equalising
machinery as opposed to a merely an advisory body cannot be too strongly emphasised.
Conclusions on Equalisation
Appropriate
provisions of equalisation are crucial to the success
of our proposed federation. However, mere fiscal equalisation
of the vertical type is not sufficient for the purpose. Horizontal equalisation is vital to ensure both the revenue capacities
and funding for the expenditure needs of all the states of the proposed federation.
Even achievement of vertical and horizontal fiscal balance on its own might
not be able to ensure uniform standard of living conditions and the same level
of prosperity throughout the territories of the federation. This will call
for what I have labelled as 'regional equalisation' to establish broadly uniform levels of economic
development among all the states of the federation. This, in turn, calls for
the establishment of an independent financial institution entrusted with the
task of allocating resources between the federation and the states and between
the states inter se to bring about the goal of equalisation.
In most Commonwealth federations the financial institution in question acts
in an advisory capacity, the final decision on the matter being vested in
the federal government. My own preference would be to vest the equalisation
decision-making power (as distinct from its being merely a recommendation)
in the financial institution itself. The relevant measures ought to be embodied
in the federal constitution giving the institution the appropriate status
and independent authority to take the necessary measures to bring up the relatively
backward regions to the common level of economic growth and performance. It
is hoped that the equalisation measures recommended
here will lay the foundation of a durable and successful federation, sine
qua non, for the preservation of peace and security in this region.
Summary of the Recommendations
- It
is recommended that the parties to the conflict in Sudan agree to the federal solution to the problem. That is to say, different regions of the
country including the southern provinces will have maximum autonomy under
the proposed federal constitution within the framework of one country.
The constituent units of the federation are to be called ‘provinces’. The precise number of the provinces and
their boundaries are to be negotiated and agreed between the parties.
THIS WILL REQUIRE A ROUNDTABLE CONFERENCE OF ALL THE PARTIES TO THE CONFLICT
IN SUDAN TO DISCUSS THE FUTURE OF THE COUNTRY AS A WHOLE. TALKS BETWEEN
THE GOVERNMENT AND ONE OR TWO PARTIES, INVOLVING ONE OR MORE SPECIFIC REGIONS
( SUCH AS SOUTHERN SUDAN ALONE) WOULD NOT BE APPROPRIATE FOR THE PURPOSE
OF FINDING A FEDERAL SOLUTION TO THE PROBLEM.
The dangers of adopting a partial solution as opposed to a comprehensive
settlement are becoming apparent.Over the past two years Sudan has settled
one long-brewing rebel conflict in the south only to see a new one arise
in the wetern province of Darfur. Now another new conflict has started in
the eastern Red Sea State ( in June 2005). Heavy fighting was reported around
the town of Tokar,half way between Port Sudan and the Eritrean border. The
Eastern Front created in February 2005 by eastern Sudan's two main dissident
factions, the Beja Congress and Free Lions launched the first military operation
against the government on 19 th June 2005 near Tokar. John Garang, the SPLM/A
leader who signed a peace deal with the government in January 2005 was reported
to have sympathised with the Darfur and the eastern Sudan question on the
ground that the inhabitants of those regions complain of marginalisation
by the central government. The fighting has sparked fears that a new Darfur-type
of conflict will open up amid peace talks in Nigeria involving the government
and the western rebels in Darfur and the implementation of the Khartoum-SPLM/A
agreement under which an interim constitution was adopted in the summer
of 2005.
The interim constitution ( which was designed to implement the north-south
agreement) allocates 52% of government and parliament posts to the ruling
National Congress Party, 28% to SPLM, 20% to northern and southern opposition
parties but none to those in other parts of the country including the east
and the west which are in a state of rebellion. This is incompatible with the federal principle under which every
province of the country will be represented in the institutions of the central
government as well as having its own self- government. The wealth sharing
agreement providing inter alia that 50% of the oil revenue produced in Southern
Sudan will be allocated to the Government of Southern Sudan might be inconsistent
with the regional equalisation principle enunciated by this author. CONSEQUENTLY
ADOPTION OF THE FAZAL PROPOSAL FOR A FEDERAL CONSTITUTION WILL REQUIRE RE-NEGOTIATION
OF SOME OF THE PROVISIONS OF THE 2004 AGREEMENT ON WEALTH SHARING.
This proposal is one of a comprehensive settlement of the conflict as opposed
to a partial settlement that has been negotiated recently (in 2004) between
the Government of Sudan and the leading rebel group in the south of the
country. It might appear that the negotiation made some progress. However,
the conflict in the western part of Sudan (the Darfur conflict) with its
humanitarian catastrophe demonstrates that no progress is possible without
a comprehensive settlement involving all the parties to the dispute.
The Darfur conflict is essentially a tribal one – mainly between the nomadic
tribes who need to move from one area to another with their cattle during
the dry season in search of grass and water and the settled tribes in the
specific regions. The Fazal Proposal envisages a permanent settlement of
the nomadic tribes by way of ‘equalisation’ among the different provinces
of the proposed federation and uniform standard of living throughout the
country. This is likely to involve the development of industry, agriculture,
soil conservation, afforestation etc of the desert/arid regions (cf. the
website article of the author of the Fazal Proposal entitled “How to Avoid
Nuclear War between India and Pakistan”) through the utilisation of water
resources available during the rainy season. HOWEVER, TRANSITIONAL PROVISIONS
HAVE TO BE MADE FOR THE NOMADIC TRIBES ON THE “RESERVED LANDS” TO BE PREPARED
FOR GRAZING THEIR CATTLE DURING THE DRY SEASONS PENDING THEIR PERMANENT
SETTLEMENT IN THE AREAS HABITUALLY SUITED TO THEIR LIVING. If the proposed
reserved areas were to cross the boundaries of one province into another
then the areas concerned would have to be designated “federal reserved areas”
and would come under the federal jurisdiction.
However, it should be emphasised that the transitional provision for the
nomadic tribes for grazing their cattle is dsesigned only for the dry season
of the year and not for their permanent settlement on the reserved lands
for the whole year. This is to avoid disturbing the tribal/electoral composition
of the population of the areas concerned . Otherwise the resident tribes
of the localities might find themselves to be in a minority in their respective
areas for the purposes of their electoral representation on the relevant
governing bodies.
These recommendations for resolution of the Darfur conflict would be equally
relevant to the countries situated along the southern edge of Sahara desert.
In all these countries including NIGERIA the nomadic tribes from the north
move south during the dry season in search of water and grass for their
cattle on to the lands of the settled tribes . As a result tribal conflicts
develop. Therefore greening of the desert ,afforestation,soil conservation
and development of agriculture,industry etc.in the desert/semi-desert areas
would provide for an environment for the permanent settlement of the nomadic
tribes in the long run.However, transitional arrangements would have to
be made for 'reserved lands' where the nomadic tribes would be able to graze
their cattle during the dry season pending their permanent settlement as
contemplated in the greening of the desert. The same recommendations might
be valid for the eastern, northern and the western edges of Sahara desert.
Eventually the whole of Sahara desert could be planned for 'greening' by
way of afforestation, soil conservation, development of agriculture ( adopting
modern methos of farming), industry etc.This is likely to require irrigation
and a sub-continental approach involving collaboration among the countries
concerned i.e.concerted actions for greening the desert by all the countries
around Sahara. Such a transformation of the landscape could bring about
a climatic change and rainfall in the area.
GLOBAL DIMMING:
Scientists looking at five decades of sunlight measurements have reached
the disturbing conclusion that the amount of solar energy reaching the Earth's
surface has been gradually declining. Dimming appears to be caused by air
pollution. Burning of coal, oil and wood, whether in cars, power stations
or cooking fires produces not only visible carbon dioxide (the principal
greenhouse gas responsible for global warming) but also tiny airborne particles
of soot, ash, sulphur compounds and other pollutants.
The visible air pollution reflects sunlight back into space, preventing
it from reaching the Earth's surface. Furtheremore, the pollution changes
the optical properties of clouds. Because the particles seed the water droplets,
polluted clouds contain a larger number of droplets than unpolluted clouds.
This makes them more reflective than they would otherwise be, again reflecting
the Sun's rays back into space. Scientists are now worried that dimming,
by cooling the air over the sub-tropical parts of the worlds such as Ethiopia
and sub-Saharan Africa caused drought which claimed millions of lives in
the 1970s and 1980s. This phenomenon was repeated again in 2005 affecting
Ethiopia and sub Saharan countries such as Niger, Mali, Mauritania and the
neighbouring countries.
Normally the hot air over these areas attracts wet air from the tropical
parts of Africa and brings about rainfall. However, cooling of atmosphere
in these areas through industrial pollution in Europe and North America
prevents this happening thereby disturbing the usual pattern of rainfall
resulting in drought and famine. [The source of this information was made
available in the BBC's Horizon programmes broadcast in the United Kingdom
on 13 and 15 January 2005]. A nuclear war, global or local, which can produce
a large amount of soot in the atmosphere (which could linger in the upper
atmosphere for up to a decade) will have similar effects in cooling the
air by several degrees centirigrade. This is liable to affect the world
climate with consequences for food production.
This is the reason why this author has serious reservations about the proposal
to cool the atmosphere above the earth. Currently the scientists are trying
to devise various means of cooling the air in order to deal with the consequences
of global warming. One of such consequences has been the damage to the tropical
forests due to the appearance of insects in the trees. The scientists ought
to develop appropriate treatment for the trees against such pests and diseases
rather than cooling the earth's atmosphere.
Greening of the Sahara Desert (which is likely to discharge moisture into
the atmosphere and bring about rainfall in the area) might be the only way
to deal with the consequences of global climatic change resulting in drought
and famine in the sub-Saharan countries of Africa. Trees absorb carbon dioxide from the air. Consequently greening
of the desert by way of afforestation is likely to have the effect of reducing
the carbon level of the atmosphere. Therefore afforestation of deserts in
the northern and southern hemispheres of this planet could play an important
part in achieving the objective of reducing the overall level of carbon
dioxide emissions.
- The
current militias are to be integrated into a federal defence force, the
provinces retaining their own police force for law and order purposes only.
Private militias are to be disbanded, disarmed and banned.
- The
federal model to be adopted should be based on the one constructed in the
work of Dr M A Fazal (A Federal Constitution to
the United Kingdom – An Alternative to Devolution [Dartmouth/Ashgate 1997]) providing for [A] the maximum of autonomy
of the provinces consistent with the federal structure; [B] a role in foreign
affairs for the provinces; and [C] regional parity among the provinces ensuring
a uniform standard of living throughout the territories of the federation.
- The
Sharia law will apply to Muslims only and not to non-Muslims,
irrespective of provinces where the person or persons concerned might be
resident. Both the provincial and
federal courts will administer the Sharia law
throughout the federation.
- The
jurisdiction over the mines and minerals including oil and gas will be divided
between the federal government and the provinces following the model of
the USA, as set out above (i.e. the federal government having an exclusive
jurisdiction over offshore oil and gas and having a parallel jurisdiction
over the in-land ones with the provinces). The federal government and the
provinces would be free to develop administrative collaboration/cooperation
on the issue (e.g. oil and gas), not excluding the possibility of further
sharing of the income therefrom.
- Whilst
the federal civil services will be open to all Sudanese strictly on merits,
the provincial civil service will be staffed solely by residents in the
province. This will be the only exception
to the principle of non-discrimination to be embodied in the federal constitution.
- The
offices of the president and vice-president should rotate between a northerner
and a southerner if the US
model of presidential system is adopted in Sudan. Alternatively, if the
British system of parliamentary government is chosen, then the office of
the prime minister and that of the president should similarly rotate between
a northerner and a southerner.
[It is thought that a non-Muslim head of state would be unacceptable to
the Muslims of Sudan. This is said to be the legacy of Mahdi who rose against
Egyptian misgovernment in 1883 and proclaimed himself to be the Khalifa.
An examination of this issue is called for. In the context of the proposed
federal constitution for Sudan, two models of government fall to be considered,
viz. the US model and the British model. The US model with the president
as the holder of real power in the federal government and a vice-president
who steps in as the president in case the president dies or becomes incapable
of performing his duties. Very often the speaker of parliament plays this
role of the president in waiting. Occasionally the chief justice of the
supreme court is also assigned this role, as in Bangladesh. The US President
is both the ceremonial head of state (i.e. the titular or constitutional
head of state) and the holder of real power. In this respect, the president
is comparable to the holder of office of Khalifa in Islamic history. If
the Muslim Sudan finds it unacceptable to have a non-Muslim president who
assumes both the roles i.e. that of a ceremonial head of state and a president
who exercises real power in the country, then they ought to consider the
British model of government for adoption in Sudan. Under the latter model,
the office of the constitutional and ceremonial head of state (who exercises
no real power in the state) and that of the holders of effective power are
vested in two different persons i.e. the monarch or a president, and the
prime minister.
Since the Government of Sudan is negotiating the question of power-sharing
with the SPLA, presumably it is not opposed to sharing the powers of the
effective holder of power i.e. those of the prime minister sharing some
of his power with a deputy prime minister. On this basis the ceremonial
or constitutional head of state who exercises no real power i.e. the president
could be a Muslim. The prime minister, the holder of real power in the state,
would be a Muslim. However, he would share some of his powers with a deputy
prime minister who could be a non-Muslim from the south. The powers exercised
by the current Deputy Prime Minister of the United Kingdom provide an illustration
of this approach and could be instructive for the purpose of finding a solution
to the problem in Sudan.
The Office of the Deputy Prime Minister was created in the United Kingdom
as a central government department in its own right in May 2002 and key
responsibilities for regional and local government, fire, housing and regeneration
were placed within its jurisdiction.]
- The
Human Rights provisions including a non-discrimination clause (prohibiting
discrimination on the grounds of race, colour, language and religion, but
excepting the provincial civil service and the rotating offices of the president,
vice-president/prime minister-president) shall form part of the federal
constitution.
- The
issue of power sharing is dealt with by the provisions of this proposal
[A] providing for the rotation of the offices of the president/vice-president
or of prime minister/president; [B] a meaningful share of power for the
provinces via the composition and powers of the upper house of the federal
parliaments; and [C] by the participation of the residents in each province
in the provincial civil service. Other
services, federal and provincial, ought to be open to all Sudanese strictly
on merits.
- The
question of wealth-sharing is dealt with in this proposal [A] by the provisions
of distribution of jurisdiction over mines and minerals, including in particular
oil and gas between the federal government and the provinces; and [B] by
the requirement of regional equalisation between the provinces coupled with
‘vertical’ and ‘horizontal’ equalisation.
According to the joint communiqué issued on the First Session of the
Political Committee Task Force on Sudan of the Intergovernmental Authority
on Development (IGAD) dated 20th July 2002, the Government of the
Sudan and the Sudanese People’s Liberation Movement/Army (SPLM/A) perceived
the outstanding issues to be [A] the issues of state and religion, [B] self-determination
for the people of south Sudan, [C] power-sharing, [D] wealth-sharing and [E]
Human Rights. It is submitted that
these issues have been adequately dealt with under this proposal and that
the people of south Sudan should
opt for this federal solution to the problem.
The solution,
as proposed here, calls for public discussion and consideration by the appropriate
authorities.
This document may be referred to as the ‘Fazal
Proposal for a Federal Solution to the Conflict in Sudan’.
Back to home page
Email: mafazalntu@yahoo.co.uk