The Corporate Use of Prison Labor in America


 
    The issues surrounding the corporate use of prison labor are by no means new; prison industries have basically existed since the establishment of the first prison in America. Many people strongly object to the use of prison labor by corporations and the state or federal government. These people condemn prison labor programs, stating that they are exploiting cheap labor. Those who oppose the use of prison labor argue that it is a violation of human rights and proclaim that it is slavery. As the rate of incarceration increases, the cost of maintaining the prison system also increases. Prison industries enable prisons to be generally self-sufficient institutions. If the burden of providing the funds to maintain the prison system was placed on taxpayers alone, there would be a large upheaval. There seems to be no obvious alternative solutions. Most of the other conventional forms of punishment are considered extremely inhumane by the American culture. It is necessary that the history, the nature, and the views that surround this issue be addressed before a solid opinion is formed.
    The first prison in America was built in Auburn, New York in 1817, and a factory was run within the prison shortly after. This practice was called the contract system. In the early days prisoners were also leased out to people, "to be housed, fed, and worked as slaves" (Browne, 1995 p.2). This was named, "the convict leasing system". In 1840, prison industries were considered the most cost efficient and prosperous method of punishment. The former, "slave codes", were reestablished as the, "black codes", after the civil war. Because many blacks were jailed for breaking these laws, it is theorized that the prisons in the south became a way for the, "power, race and economic relationships of slavery", to remain in tact. The black prisoners were sometimes then leased to plantations, so those roles of slavery could be reenacted. Mississippi was the first state to cease to use the convict leasing system, in 1894. However, it was not until the 1930s that all of the states aborted this system (Browne, 1995). It was also during the 1930s that the prison industries were outlawed by congress. This action was in response to the scarcity of jobs during the Great Depression (Wright, 1994). Georgia was the first state to establish the use of, "chain-gangs", which did not end until the 1950s (Browne, 1995). On December 6, 1945, Congress passed a law that forbade the establishment or operation of any business that was completely controlled by the government (Martin). In 1979 a law that made prison industries legal once again. This law included the requirement that, prison industries had to obey certain regulations to remain functional. The law also made the use of prison labor an issue of debate again (Sexton, 1995).
    The AFL-CIO supports prison work programs that meet specific standards. They support programs that provide convicts with job skills that will be useful after the completion of their sentence. The AFL-CIO also approves programs that, "produce goods and services that are exclusively for government use and may not be sold to the government". They advocate that prisoners should be paid an amount that is equal to the existent wages of the public for similar work, with necessary withdrawals made (Sexton, 1995). These withdrawals are used to pay for their accommodations, taxes, and victim compensation (Wright, 1994). They oppose programs that use prison laborers to break strikes or replace free workers (AFL-CIO, 1997). Reese Erlich (1995) reports, that a history of the conflict of interests between union and industries that utilize prison laborers exists. In 1885, the state use of prison labor to build the capital in Texas caused the skilled granite cutters union to boycott the job. When the owners of a coalmine in Briceville, Tennessee tried to force workers to agree to never unionize; the miners went on strike. Then, the owners hired prisoners to continue production; this infuriated the miners. They attacked the mine and freed the prisoners. Their current position in favor of prison industries is perhaps influenced by the federal regulations that now exist. Joint-venture programs are required to consult local unions before the construction of the enterprise. Despite this law, the company rarely consults unions (Reynolds). Most of the other federal regulations that apply to prison industries are obeyed. Joint ventures are forced to pay their employees a wage that is standard in the open market. It is also necessary that prison-based industries do not cause the elimination of currently held positions of employment in the community (Sexton, 1995). These regulations are in compliance with the desires of the AFL-CIO. The AFL-CIO states that it will continue to pursue the instatement of federal and state laws that ensure job security for union workers.
     The replacement of public jobs by prisoners, is one of the concerns that are used to support opinions that oppose the use of prison labor. There are several ways in which a community can benefit from the institution of a prison based industry. Prison industries require resources for production. The need for resources can create more jobs in the community. 73% of every $1.00 made by Federal Prison Industries (FPI), "is spent directly on materials, equipment, and services from private businesses" (Reynolds p.1). Prison labor programs are a type of economic development that teaches us, "the cheapest and most efficient or effective way", to produce (Reynolds p.2). Because the skills required completing the tasks in prison labor programs are mostly minimal; they spare, "productive resources for new tasks" (Reynolds p.2). Many communities actually compete for the establishment of prison industries nearby (Bloomer, 1997). Another way that people can profit from the growth of prison based joint ventures, is the profitability of their stocks. Because these companies answer to share holders, they are very concerned with ways to cut costs (Silverstein, 1997). Joint ventures also allow prisons to be mostly self-sufficient, even though, "comparisons of operational costs (between public and private institutions) indicated little difference and/or mixed results" (qtd. in Bloomer 2). This is because the state is still held responsible for the costs of many of the necessary benefits, like health benefits, that regular workers receive. Prison industries are generally more lucrative than non-prison industries in America; many corporations argue that prison industries have an unfair advantage. However, many American companies have relocated to other countries because, of the availability of cheap labor. In comparison, the American economy is advanced more by prison industries than by companies who utilize foreign labor (Bloomer, 1997). Prison labor programs that are completely ran by federal or state governments create or save money. By employing prisoners to help control fires and conserve forests, California's Department of Forestry is able to save more than 70 million dollars annually (Browne,1995). Prison industries are clearly not detrimental to the American economy.
    The convicts and the correctional facilities benefit from the creation of prison-based joint ventures. Prisoners'  sentences are often decreased by one day for every day that they work. Furthermore, punishments such as the removal of some or all privileges, longer sentences, and possibly solitary confinement can be a consequence, if a prisoner refuses to work (Browne, 1995). The  inmates that participate in work programs are happy to have a source of income so they can send money to their families or save until they are released. Most prisoners appreciate working because it gives them something productive to do with their time. Correctional officers and guards are pleased that the prisoners are busy; because, many of the disruptions that occur in prisons are due to the idleness of  the convicts (Sexton, 1995). Several work programs are intended to provide job-skills that the inmates can utilize when they are released, but some programs such as California's are not at all concerned with teaching  prisoners any new skills. Californian prisoners are evaluated to determine how they will be classified and what correctional  facility they will be placed in, based on the job-skills that they possess. Inmates are also categorized by the amount of time they will be allowed to work (Browne, 1995).
     One of the many objections to the use of prison labor is the accusation that it is a form of slavery. These people say that prisoners do not receive a fair amount of pay and they are forced to work. The average wage of inmates is less than a dollar an hour, but that is after the costs of their room and board and the compensation of their victims have been subtracted. Prisoners are not forced to work. Despite the fact that inmates may be punished for refusing to work and receive incentives if they participate in work programs, the prisoners are allowed to choose. Many people support their comparison of prison labor to slavery by citing incidences of fatalities, injuries, or abuse that occur while prisoners are working. Reynolds points out that injuries and fatalities are likely to result from any strenuous manual labor such as mining or building railroads. Accidents do happen. Prisoners are also vulnerable to abuse whether they are working or not. State governments should inspect private and public prisons more thoroughly. Extreme conditions imposed on prisoners such as those practiced by chain gangs should be reformed. Even though, prisoners are no longer chained together (due to a lawsuit in 1996), prison guards have an outrageous amount of control over the prisoners' futures. Guards can, "at their own discretion, extend the duration of the prisoners' punishment" (Browne 1995). There should be a system established that would repeal the position of the guards as the ultimate authority. During the late 1800s prisoners who were leased to private industries or plantation owners were severally maltreated, sometimes even causing their death. According to Reynolds, these incidents were a result of the, "government's failure to protect human rights in the entire prison system", not the convict leasing program (p.4).
    The American government is undeniably hypocritical in their treatment to the subject of prison labor. Although the Sumners-Ashurst Act made interstate trafficking of merchandise made by convicts a federal crime; it did not outlaw sales within a state or the exportation of goods produced by prisoners. Products made by American prisoners are often exported to China; even though, the U.S. has taken a position that strongly opposes the use of prison labor in China. China's government has prohibited the exportation of products made by convicts (Wright, 1994). American prison labor programs may not force inmates to work, but is China's system so different that it fails to observe human rights?  If the allegation that the use of prison labor is a violation of the prisoners' human rights is correct, it is then questionable if incarceration or the punishment of solitary confinement are violations as well. Where do the rights of prisoners' end? Prison work programs reduce the amount of money used by prisons, which is provided by taxpayers. After all, convicts are sent to prisons to pay their debt to society, not to become an expense of society.
    Prison industries may not be a solution to America's over-crowded prisons and high crime rates. It is essential that the roots of these problems be addressed, in order for the attainment of a true solution. This would involve a reevaluation of the goals and values of the American legal system, and researching the causes of criminal behavior. However, prison work programs do provide feasible answer to the rising costs of the prison system and over-crowded prisons. Prison work programs are sometimes even successful in contributing to the rehabilitation of inmates. Prison industries provide many favorable results for the inmates, the prisons, the employers, the economy, and the communities involved. Prison work programs are not flawless, but realistic improvements can be made. Morgan O. Reynolds suggests three revisions that would create a fairer market with the presence of prison industries. His first suggestion is, that prison labor should be, "applied to products that have negligible domestic competitive effects" (pg.3). He also proposes that interstate trafficking of merchandise made by convicts should be legalized. Finally, state and federal governments should not require that products made by prisoners be sold only to government agencies. These changes would allow fair competition between prison industries and non-prison industries. The benifits of prison work programs outweigh their repairable flaws. They should remain active until a better solution to the problems of America's criminal-justice system is found.

Home Next Labor Index