******************************************************
PAN Discussion Group TUESDAY February 27th 2007
Subject: Immigration
******************************************************
Location: Irving Park and Lincoln - ish RSVP for details
Time: 7pm to 10pm - ish
Bring drinks and snacks to share
After my moaning last month lots of people sent me articles – Thank you! Picking the best was difficult. I edited out the most prominent duplicates but there is still more material than I generally would send. However it’s all good easily readable stuff.
The new Oobleck production, ‘The Strangerer’, is by their master writer Mickle Maher. We should think about a theater outing: www.theateroobleck.com
General:
The articles are the basis for the discussion and reading them helps give us some common ground and focus for the discussion, especially where we would otherwise be ignorant of the issues. The discussions are not intended as debates or arguments, rather they should be a chance to explore ideas and issues in a constructive forum. Feel free to bring along other stuff you've read on this, related subjects or on topics the group might be interested in for future meetings.
GROUND RULES:
* Temper the urge to speak with the discipline to listen and leave space for others
* Balance the desire to teach with a passion to learn
* Hear what is said and listen for what is meant
* Marry your certainties with others' possibilities
* Reserve judgment until you can claim the understanding we seek
Any problems let me know...
847-963-1254
Colin
tysoe2@yahoo.com
The Articles:
************************************************************************
The Immigration Equation
New York Times Magazine, July 9, 2006 Author: Roger Lowenstein
The day I met George Borjas,cloistered in his office at the John F. Kennedy School of Government at Harvard while graduate students from Russia, India, China and maybe Mexico mingled in the school cafe, sipping coffee and chattering away in all their tongues, the United States Senate was hotly debating what to do about the country's immigration policy. Borjas professed to be unfazed by the goings-on in Washington. A soft-spoken man, he stressed repeatedly that his concern was not to make policy but to derive the truth. To Borjas, a Cuban immigrant and the pre-eminent scholar in his field, the truth is pretty obvious: immigrants hurt the economic prospects of the Americans they compete with. And now that the biggest contingent of immigrants are poorly educated Mexicans, they hurt poorer Americans, especially African-Americans, the most.
Borjas has been making this case
-- which is based on the familiar concept of supply and demand -- for
more than a decade. But the more elegantly he has made it, it seems, the
less his colleagues concur. "I think I have proved it," he eventually
told me, admitting his frustration. "What I don't understand is why
people don't agree with me."
It turns out that Borjas's seemingly self-evident premise -- that more
job seekers from abroad mean fewer opportunities, or lower wages, for
native workers -- is one of the most controversial ideas in labor
economics. It lies at the heart of a national debate, which has been
encapsulated (if not articulated) by two very different
immigration bills: one,
passed by the House of Representatives, which would toughen laws against
undocumented workers and probably force many of them to leave the
country; and one in the Senate, a measure that would let most of them
stay.
You can find economists to substantiate the position of either chamber,
but the consensus of most is that, on balance,
immigration is good for the
country. Immigrants provide scarce labor, which lowers prices in much
the same way global trade does. And overall, the newcomers modestly
raise Americans' per capita income. But the impact is unevenly
distributed; people with means pay less for taxi rides and household
help while the less-affluent command lower wages and probably pay more
for rent.
The debate among economists is whether low-income workers are hurt a lot
or just a little -- and over what the answer implies for
U.S. policy. If you believe Borjas, the answer is
troubling. A policy designed with only Americans' economic well-being in
mind would admit far fewer Mexicans, who now account for about 3 in 10
immigrants. Borjas, who emigrated from Cuba in 1962, when he was 12 (and
not long after soldiers burst into his family's home and ordered them at
gunpoint to stand against a wall), has asserted that the issue, indeed,
is "Whom should the United States let in?"
Such a bald approach carries an overtone of the ethnic selectivity that
was a staple of the immigration
debates a century ago. It makes many of Borjas's colleagues
uncomfortable, and it is one reason that the debate is so charged.
Another reason is that many of the scholars who disagree with Borjas
also hail from someplace else -- like gardeners and seamstresses, a
surprising number of Ph.D. economists in the U.S. are foreign-born.
Easily the most influential of Borjas's critics is David Card, a
Canadian who teaches at Berkeley. He has said repeatedly that, from an
economic standpoint, immigration
is no big deal and that a lot of the opposition to it is most likely
social or cultural. "If Mexicans were taller and whiter, it would
probably be a lot easier to deal with," he says pointedly.
Economists in Card's camp tend to frame the issue as a puzzle -- a great
economic mystery because of its very success. The puzzle is this: how is
the U.S. able to absorb its immigrants so easily?
After all, 21 million immigrants, about 15 percent of the labor force,
hold jobs in the U.S., but the country has nothing close to that many
unemployed. (The actual number is only seven million.) So the majority
of immigrants can't literally have "taken" jobs; they must be doing jobs
that wouldn't have existed had the immigrants not been here.
The economists who agree with Card also make an intuitive point,
inevitably colored by their own experience. To the Israeli-born
economist whose father lived through the Holocaust or the Italian who
marvels at America's ability to integrate workers from around the world,
America's diversity -- its knack for synthesizing newly arrived parts
into a more vibrant whole -- is a secret of its strength. To which
Borjas, who sees a different synthesis at work, replies that, unlike his
colleagues, the people arriving from Oaxaca, Mexico, are unlikely to
ascend to a university faculty. Most of them did not finish high school.
"The trouble with the stories that American journalists write about
immigration," he told me, "is
they all start with a story about a poor mother whose son grows up to
become.. . ." and his voice trailed off as if to suggest that whatever
the particular story -- that of a C.E.O., a ballplayer or even a story
like his own -- it would not prove anything about
immigration. What economists
aim for is to get beneath the anecdotes. Is
immigration still the engine
of prosperity that the history textbooks describe? Or is it a boon to
business that is destroying the livelihoods of the poorest workers --
people already disadvantaged by such postmodern trends as globalization,
the decline of unions and the computer?
$( The Lopsided-Skill-Mix Problem $)
This spring, while militias on the prowl for illegal immigrants were
converging on the Arizona border and, on the other side of the political
fence, immigrant protesters were taking to the streets, I sampled the
academic literature and spent some time with Borjas and Card and various
of their colleagues. I did not expect concurrence, but I hoped to
isolate what we know about the economic effects of
immigration from what is mere
conjecture. The first gleaning from the Ivory Tower came as a surprise.
All things being equal, more foreigners and indeed more people of any
stripe do not mean either lower wages or higher unemployment. If they
did, every time a baby was born, every time a newly minted graduate
entered the work force, it would be bad news for the labor market. But
it isn't. Those babies eat baby food; those graduates drive automobiles.
As Card likes to say, "The demand curve also shifts out." It's jargon,
but it's profound. New workers add to the supply of labor, but since
they consume products and services, they add to the demand for it as
well. "Just because Los Angeles is bigger than Bakersfield doesn't mean
L.A. has more unemployed than Bakersfield," Card observes.
In theory, if you added 10 percent to the population -- or even doubled
it -- nothing about the labor market would change. Of course, it would
take a little while for the economy to adjust. People would have to
invest money and start some new businesses to hire all those newcomers.
The point is, they would do it. Somebody would realize that the
immigrants needed to eat and would open a restaurant; someone else would
think to build them housing. Pretty soon there would be new jobs
available in kitchens and on construction sites. And that has been going
on since the first boat docked at Ellis Island.
But there's a catch. Individual native workers are less likely to be
affected if the immigrants resemble the society they are joining -- not
physically but in the same mix of skills and educational backgrounds.
For instance, if every immigrant were a doctor, the theory is, it would
be bad for doctors already here. Or as Borjas asked pointedly of me,
what if the U.S. created a special visa just for magazine writers? All
those foreign-born writers would eat more meals, sure, but (once they
mastered English, anyway), they would be supplying only one type of
service -- my type. Bye-bye fancy assignments.
During the previous immigrant wave, roughly from 1880 to 1921 (it ended
when the U.S. established restrictive quotas based on country of
origin), the immigrants looked pretty much like the America into which
they were assimilating. At the beginning of the 20th century, 9 of 10
American adults did not have high-school diplomas, nor did the vast
majority of immigrants. Those Poles and Greeks and Italians made the
country more populous, but they did not much change the makeup of the
labor market.
This time it's different. The proportion of foreign-born, at 12 percent,
remains below the peak of 15 percent recorded in 1890. But compared with
the work force of today, however, the skill mix of immigrants is
lopsided. About the same proportion have college degrees (though a
higher proportion of immigrants are post-graduates). But many more --
including most of the those who have furtively slipped across the
Mexican border -- don't have high-school diplomas.
The latest estimate is that the United States has 11.5 million
undocumented foreigners, and it's those immigrants -- the illegal ones
-- who have galvanized Congress. The sponsor of the House legislation,
Representative James Sensenbrenner, a Republican from Wisconsin, says
bluntly that illegals are bad for the U.S. economy. His bill would
require employers to verify the status of their workers from a national
database and levy significant penalties on violators. But H.R. 4437
isn't primarily an economics bill -- it's an expression of outrage over
the porousness of America's borders. Among many other enforcement
measures, the bill forces the U.S. to build hundreds of miles of fencing
on its Southern border.
The Senate bill is irreducibly complex (more than 800 pages), but
basically, it seeks to cure the problem of illegals by bringing them in
from the shadows. Those already here would be able to continue working
and get on track toward a more normalized status. In the future,
employers could bring in guest workers -- what Senate draftsmen refer to
hopefully as temporary workers -- as long as they paid them the going
wage.
This latter bill, the product of an alliance between John McCain and
Edward Kennedy, isn't really an economics bill, either, at least not the
way economists see it. Its premise is that if you legalize undocumented
people and reinforce the borders, then whatever negative impact
immigrants have on the labor market will go away. The theory is that
newly minted green-card holders, no longer having deportation to fear,
will stick up for their rights and for higher wages too. Interestingly,
some big labor unions, like the Service Employees International Union,
are supporters. But economists are skeptical. For one thing, after the
U.S. gave amnesty to the nearly three million undocumented workers who
were in the country in 1986, their wages didn't budge. Second,
economists, as you might expect, say market forces like supply and
demand, not legal status, are what determine wages.
It baffles some economists that Congress pays so little heed to their
research, but then immigration
policy has never been based on economics. Economic fears played a part
in the passage of the exclusionary acts against Chinese in the late 19th
and early 20th centuries, and in the 1920's of quotas (aimed in
particular at people from southern and eastern Europe), but they were
mostly fueled by xenophobia. They were supplanted in the Civil Rights
era by the Immigration and
Nationality Act of 1965, which ended quotas and established a new
priority based on family reunification. That law, also sponsored by
Kennedy, had nothing to do with economics, either. It made the chief
criterion for getting in having a relative who was already here.
If economists ran the country, they would certainly take in more
immigrants who, like them, have advanced degrees. (The U.S., which is
hugely dependent on foreigners to fill certain skilled occupations like
scientific research and nursing, does admit a relative handful of
immigrants each year on work visas.) Canada and Australia admit
immigrants primarily on the basis of skills, and one thing the
economists agree on is that high earners raise the national income by
more than low earners. They are also less of a burden on the tax rolls.
With the exception of a few border states, however, the effect of
immigration on public-sector
budgets is small, and the notion that undocumented workers in particular
abuse the system is a canard. Since many illegals pay into Social
Security (using false ID numbers), they are actually subsidizing the
U.S. Treasury. And fewer than 3 percent of immigrants of any stripe
receive food stamps. Also, and contrary to popular wisdom, undocumented
people do support local school districts, since, indirectly as renters
or directly as homeowners, they pay property taxes. Since they tend to
be poor, however, they contribute less than the average. One estimate is
that immigrants raise state and local taxes for everyone else in the
U.S. by a trivial amount in most states, but by as much as $1,100 per
household per year in California. They are certainly a burden on
hospitals and jails but, it should be noted, poor legal workers,
including those who are native born, are also a burden on the health
care system.
$( Parsing the Wage Gap $)
Economists focus on Mexicans not because many are undocumented but
because, relative to the rest of the labor force, Mexicans have far
fewer skills. And Mexicans and other Central Americans (who tend to have
a similar economic background) are arriving and staying in this country
at a rate of more than 500,000 a year. Their average incomes are vastly
lower than those both of native-born men and of other immigrants.
Native-born workers: $45,400
All immigrants: $37,000
Mexican immigrants: $22,300
The reason Mexicans earn much less than most Americans is their daunting
educational deficit. More than 60 percent of Mexican immigrants are
dropouts; fewer than 10 percent of today's native workers are.
That stark contrast conveys, to economists, two important facts. One is
that Mexicans are supplying a skill level that is much in demand. It
doesn't just seem that Americans don't want to be hotel chambermaids,
pick lettuce or repair roofs; it's true. Most gringos are too educated
for that kind of work. The added diversity, the complementariness of
skills, that Mexicans bring is good for the economy as a whole. They
perform services that would otherwise be more expensive and in some
cases simply unavailable.
The Americans who are unskilled, however, must compete with a
disproportionate number of immigrants. One of every four high-school
dropouts in the U.S. was born in Mexico, an astonishing ratio given that
the proportion of Mexicans in the overall labor force is only 1 in 25.
So it's not magazine writers who see their numbers expanding; it's
Americans who are, or would be, working in construction, restaurants,
household jobs, unskilled manufacturing and so forth.
That's the theory. But economists have had a hard time finding evidence
of actual harm. For starters, they noticed that societies with lots of
immigrants tend, if anything, to be more prosperous, not less. In the
U.S., wages in cities where immigrants have clustered, like New York,
have tended to be higher, not lower. Mississippi, on the other hand,
which has the lowest per-capita income of any state, has had very few
immigrants.
That doesn't necessarily mean that immigrants caused or even contributed
to high wages; it could be they simply go where the demand is greatest
-- that their presence is an effect of high wages. As statisticians are
wont to remind us, "Correlation does not imply causation." (The fact
that hospitals are filled with sick people doesn't mean hospitals make
you sick.) Maybe without immigrants, wages in New York would be even
higher.
And certainly, wages of the unskilled have been a source of worry for
years. From 1970 to 1995, wages for high-school dropouts, the group that
has been the most affected by immigrants, plummeted by more than 30
percent, after adjusting for inflation. Look at the following averages
(all for male workers):
College graduates: $73,000
People with some college: $41,000
High-school grads: $32,000
Dropouts: $24,800
These figures demonstrate a serious problem, at least if you care about
wage inequality, and a quick glance at this list and the previous one
shows that native-born dropouts are earning only a shade more than
Mexicans working in this country. But that hardly proves that cheap
Mexican labor is to blame. For one thing, economists believe that other
factors, like the failure of Congress to raise the minimum wage,
globalization (cheap Chinese labor, that is) and the decline of unions
are equally or even more responsible. Another popular theory is that
computer technology has made skilled labor more valuable and unskilled
labor less so.
Also, when economists look closely at wage dispersion, the picture isn't
wholly consistent with the immigrants-as-culprits thesis. Look again at
the numbers: people at the top (college grads) make a lot more than
average but from the middle on down incomes are pretty compressed. Since
only dropouts are being crowded by illegal immigrants, you would expect
them to be falling further behind every other group. But they aren't;
since the mid-90's, dropouts have been keeping pace with the middle;
it's the corporate executives and their ilk at the top who are pulling
away from the pack, a story that would seem to have little to do with
immigration.
This isn't conclusive either, Borjas notes. After all, maybe without
immigrants, dropouts would have done much better than high-school grads.
Economists look for the "counterfactual," or what would have happened
had immigrants not come. It's difficult to tell, because in the real
world, there is always a lot more going on -- an oil shock, say, or a
budget deficit -- than the thing whose effect you are studying. To
isolate the effect of immigrants alone would require a sort of lab
experiment. The trouble with macroeconomics is you can't squeeze your
subjects into a test tube.
$( Marielitos in Miami, Doctors in Israel and Other Natural Experiments
$)
The academic study of immigration's
economic effects earned little attention before the subject started to
get political traction in the 1980's. Then, in 1990, Borjas, who was on
the faculty at the University of California at Santa Barbara, published
a book, "Friends or Strangers," which was mildly critical of
immigration's effects.
That same year, David Card realized that a test tube did exist. Card
decided to study the 1980 Mariel boat lift, in which 125,000 Cubans were
suddenly permitted to emigrate. They arrived in South Florida with
virtually no advance notice, and approximately half remained in the
Miami area, joining an already-sizable Cuban community and swelling the
city's labor force by 7 percent.
To Card, this produced a "natural experiment," one in which cause and
effect were clearly delineated. Nothing about conditions in the Miami
labor market had induced the Marielitos to emigrate; the Cubans simply
left when they could and settled in the city that was closest and most
familiar. So Card compared the aftershocks in Miami with the labor
markets in four cities -- Tampa, Atlanta, Houston and Los Angeles --
that hadn't suddenly been injected with immigrants.
That the Marielitos, a small fraction of whom were career criminals,
caused an upsurge in crime, as well as a more generalized anxiety among
natives, is indisputable. It was also commonly assumed that the
Marielitos were taking jobs from blacks.
But Card documented that blacks, and also other workers, in Miami
actually did better than in the control cities. In 1981, the year after
the boat lift, wages for Miami blacks were fractionally higher than in
1979; in the control cities, wages for blacks were down. The only
negative was that unemployment rose among Cubans (a group that now
included the Marielitos).
Unemployment in all of the cities rose the following year, as the
country entered a recession. But by 1985, the last year of Card's study,
black unemployment in Miami had retreated to below its level of 1979,
while in the control cities it remained much higher. Even among Miami's
Cubans, unemployment returned to pre-Mariel levels, confirming what
seemed visible to the naked eye: the Marielitos were working. Card
concluded, "The Mariel influx appears to have had virtually no effect on
the wages or unemployment rates of less-skilled workers."
Although Card offered some hypotheses, he couldn't fully explain his
results. The city's absorption of a 7 percent influx, he wrote, was
"remarkably rapid" and -- even if he did not quite say it -- an utter
surprise. Card's Mariel study hit the cloistered world of labor
economists like a thunderbolt. All of 13 pages, it was an aesthetic as
well as an academic masterpiece that prompted Card's peers to look for
other "natural" immigration
experiments. Soon after, Jennifer Hunt, an Australian-born Ph.D.
candidate at Harvard, published a study on the effects of the return
migration of ethnic French from Algeria to France in 1962, the year of
Algerian independence. Similar in spirit though slightly more negative
than the Mariel study, Hunt found that the French retour had a very mild
upward effect on unemployment and no significant effect on wages.
Rachel Friedberg, an economist at Brown, added an interesting twist to
the approach. Rather than compare the effect of
immigration across cities,
she compared it across various occupations. Friedberg's curiosity had
been piqued in childhood; born in Israel, she moved to the U.S. as an
infant and grew up amid refugee grandparents who were a constant
reminder of the immigrant experience.
She focused on an another natural experiment -- the exodus of 600,000
Russian Jews to Israel, which increased the population by 14 percent in
the early 1990's. She wanted to see if Israelis who worked in
occupations in which the Russians were heavily represented had lost
ground relative to other Israelis. And in fact, they had. But that
didn't settle the issue. What if, Friedberg wondered, the Russians had
entered less-attractive fields precisely because, as immigrants, they
were at the bottom of the pecking order and hadn't been able to find
better work? And in fact, she concluded that the Russians hadn't caused
wage growth to slacken; they had merely gravitated to positions that
were less attractive. Indeed, Friedberg's conclusion was
counterintuitive: the Russians had, if anything, improved wages of
native Israelis. She hypothesized that the immigrants competed more with
one another than with natives. The Russians became garage mechanics;
Israelis ran the garages.
$( Measuring the Hit to Wages $)
By the mid-90's, illegal immigration
was heating up as an issue in the United States, prompting a reaction in
California, where schools and other public services were beginning to
feel a strain. But academics were coalescing around the view that
immigration was essentially
benign -- that it depressed unskilled native wages by a little and
raised the average native income by a little. In 1997, a panel of the
National Academy of Sciences, which reviewed all of the literature,
estimated that immigration
during the previous decade had, at most, lowered unskilled-native wages
by 1 percent to 2 percent.
Borjas didn't buy it. In 1999 he published a second, more strident book,
"Heaven's Door." It espoused a "revisionist" view -- that
immigration caused real harm
to lower-income Americans. Borjas argued that localized studies like
Mariel were flawed, for the simple reason that labor markets in the U.S.
are linked together. Therefore, the effects of
immigration could not be
gauged by comparing one city with another.
Borjas pointed out, as did others, that more native-born Americans
started migrating out of California in the 1970's, just as Mexicans
began arriving in big numbers. Previously California was a destination
for Americans. Borjas reckoned that immigrants were pushing out
native-born Americans, and that the effect of all the new foreigners was
dispersed around the country.
The evidence of a labor surplus seemed everywhere. "If you wanted a
maid," he recalled of California during the 90's, "all you had to do was
tell your gardener, and you had one tomorrow." He felt certain that
Mexicans were depressing unskilled wages but didn't know how to prove
it.
After Borjas moved East, he had an inspiration. It was easy to show that
high-school dropouts had experienced both lower wage growth and more
competition from immigrants, but that didn't settle the point, because
so many other factors could have explained why dropouts did poorly. The
inspiration was that people compete not only against those with a like
education, but also against workers of roughly the same experience.
Someone looking for a first job at a McDonald's competes against other
unskilled entry-level job seekers. A reporter with 15 years' experience
who is vying for a promotion will compete against other veterans but not
against candidates fresh out of journalism school.
This insight enabled Borjas to break down the Census data in a way that
put his thesis to a more rigorous test. He could represent skill groups
within each age as a point on a graph. There was one point for dropouts
who were 10 years out of school, another for those who were 20 years and
30 years out. Each of these points was repeated for each decade from
1960 to 2000. And there was a similar set of points for high-school
graduates, college graduates and so forth. The points were situated on
the graph according to two variables: the horizontal axis measured the
change in the share of immigrants within each "point," the vertical axis
measured wage growth.
A result was a smattering of dots that on casual inspection might have
resembled a work of abstract art. But looking closer, the dots had a
direction: they pointed downward. Using a computer, Borjas measured the
slope: it suggested that wages fell by 3 to 4 percent for each 10
percent increase in the share of immigrants.
With this graph, Borjas could calculate that, during the 80's and 90's,
for instance, immigrants caused dropouts to suffer a 5 percent decline
relative to college graduates. In a paper published in 2003, "The Labor
Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping," Borjas termed the results "negative
and significant."
But what about the absolute effect? Assuming businesses did not hire any
of the new immigrants, Borjas's finding would translate to a hefty 9
percent wage loss for the unskilled over those two decades, and lesser
declines for other groups (which also received some immigrants). As we
know, however, as the population grows, demand rises and business do
hire more workers. When Borjas adjusted for this hiring, high-school
dropouts were still left with a wage loss of 5 percent over those two
decades, some $1,200 a year. Other groups, however, showed a very slight
gain. To many economists as well as lay folk, Borjas's findings
confirmed what seemed intuitive all along: add to the supply of labor,
and the price goes down.
To Card, however, what seems "intuitive" is often suspect. He became a
labor economist because the field is full of anomalies. "The
simple-minded theories that they teach you in economics don't work" for
the labor market, he told me. In the 90's, Card won the prestigious
Clark Medal for several studies, including Mariel and another showing
that, contrary to theory, raising the minimum wage in New Jersey
(another natural experiment) did not cause fast-food outlets to cut back
on employment.
In a recent paper, "Is the New
Immigration Really So Bad?" Card took indirect aim at Borjas
and, once again, plumbed a labor-market surprise. Despite the recent
onslaught of immigrants, he pointed out, U.S. cities still have fewer
unskilled workers than they had in 1980. Immigrants may be depriving
native dropouts of the scarcity value they might have enjoyed, but at
least in a historical sense, unskilled labor is not in surplus. America
has become so educated that immigrants merely mitigate some of the
decline in the homegrown unskilled population. Thus, in 1980, 24 percent
of the work force in metropolitan areas were dropouts; in 2000, only 18
percent were.
Card also observed that cities with more immigrants, like those in the
Sun Belt close to the Mexican border, have a far higher proportion of
dropouts. This has led to a weird unbalancing of local labor markets.
For example, 10 percent of the work force in Pittsburgh and 15 percent
in Cleveland are high-school dropouts; in Houston the figure is 25
percent, in Los Angeles, 30 percent. The immigrants aren't dispersing,
or not very quickly.
So where do all the dropouts work? Los Angeles does have a lot of
apparel manufacturers but not enough of such immigrant-intensive
businesses to account for all of its unskilled workers. Studies also
suggest that immigration
is correlated with a slight increase in unemployment. But again, the
effect is small. So the mystery is how cities absorb so many unskilled.
Card's theory is that the same businesses operate differently when
immigrants are present; they spend less on machines and more on labor.
Still, he admitted, "We are left with the puzzle of explaining the
remarkable flexibility of employment demand."
Card started thinking about this when he moved from Princeton in the
mid-90's. He noticed that everyone in Berkeley seemed to have a
gardener, "even though professors are not rich." In the U.S., which has
more unskilled labor than Europe, more people employ housecleaners. The
African-American women who held those jobs before the war, like the
Salvadorans and Guatemalans of today, weren't taking jobs; they were
creating them.
$( The Personal Is Economic $)
Though Card works on immigration
only some of the time, he and Borjas clearly have become rivals. In a
recent paper, Card made a point of referring to the "revisionist" view
as "overly pessimistic." Borjas told Business Week that Card's ideas
were "insane." ("Obviously I didn't mean he is insane; he is a very
bright guy," Borjas clarified when we talked. "The idea that you can add
15 or 20 million people and not have any effect seems crazy.") Alan B.
Krueger, an economist who is friendly with each, says, "I fear it might
become acrimonious." Card told me twice that Borjas's calculations were
"disingenuous." "Borjas has a strong view on this topic," Card said,
"almost an emotional position."
Card is more comfortable with anecdote than many scholars, and he tells
a story about his wife, who teaches English to Mexicans. In one class,
she tapped on a wall, asking a student to identify it, and the guy said,
"That's drywall." To Card, it signifies that construction is one of
those fields that soak up a disproportionate number of Mexicans; it's a
little piece of the puzzle. "Even when I was a kid in Ontario 45 years
ago," he notes, "the tobacco pickers were Jamaicans. They were terrible
jobs -- backbreaking." Card is a political liberal with thinning auburn
air and a controlled, smirky smile. His prejudices, if not his emotions,
favor immigrants. Raised by dairy farmers in Guelph, Ontario, he
remembers that Canadian cities were mostly boring while he was growing
up. The ones that attracted immigrants, like Toronto and Vancouver,
boomed and became more cosmopolitan.
"Everyone knows in trade there are winners and losers," Card says. "For
some reason it doesn't stop people from advocating free trade." He could
have said the same of Wal-Mart, which has put plenty of Mom-and-Pop
retailers out of business. In fact, any time a firm offers better or
more efficient service, somebody will suffer. But the economy grows as a
result.
"I honestly think the economic arguments are second order," Card told me
when we discussed immigration.
"They are almost irrelevant."
Card's implication is that darker forces -- ethnic prejudice, maybe, or
fear of social disruption -- is what's really motivating a lot of
anti-immigrant sentiment. Borjas, a Hispanic who has written in blunt
terms about the skill deficits of Mexicans, in particular arouses
resentment. "Mexicans aren't as good as Cubans like him," Douglas S.
Massey, a demographer at Princeton, said in a pointed swipe.
Borjas lives an assimilated life. He has a wife who speaks no Spanish,
three kids, two of whom study his mother tongue as a foreign language,
and a home in Lexington, a tony Boston suburb. Yet his mind-set often
struck me as that of an outsider -- an immigrant, if you will, to his
own profession.
When I asked the inevitable question -- did his exile experience
influence his choice of career? -- he said, "Clearly it predisposed me."
The seeds of the maverick scholar were planted the year before he left
Cuba, a searing time when the revolution was swinging decisively toward
Soviet-style communism. His family had owned a small factory that
manufactured men's pants. The factory was shut down, and the family made
ready to leave the island, but their departure was delayed by the death
of Borjas's father. The son had to attend a revolutionary school, where
the precepts of Marxism-Leninism were drilled into the future economist
with notable lack of success. One day he marched in the band and drummed
the "Internationale" in front of Fidel Castro and the visiting Yuri
Gagarin, the Soviet cosmonaut. "Since that year I have been incredibly
resistant to any kind of indoctrination," he told me -- an attitude that
surfaces in wry references to the liberal Harvard environs as the
"People's Republic of Cambridge" and to American political correctness
in general.
Borjas's family arrived with virtually no money; they got some clothing
from Catholic Charities and a one-time stipend of, as he recollects,
$100. His mother got a factory job in Miami, where they stayed several
years. Then the family moved to New Jersey. He attended Saint Peter's
College in Jersey City and got his Ph.D. at Columbia.
I asked him whether the fact that he was Cuban, the most successful
Latin subgroup, had affected his views of other Hispanics. "Look, I've
never been psychoanalyzed," he said with an air of resignation, as if he
were accustomed to hearing such loaded questions. One thing Borjas
shares with Card is a view that others treat
immigration emotionally. But
Borjas takes comfort not in anecdote but in empiricism. As he said to me
often, "The data is the data."
$( Immigrants Can Be Complementary $)
Economists on Card's side of the debate recognize that they at least
have to deal with Borjas's data -- to reconcile why the local studies
and national studies produce different results. Card shrugs it off; even
5 percent for a dropout, he observes, is only 50 to 60 cents an hour.
Giovanni Peri, an Italian working at the University of California,
Davis, had a more intriguing response. Peri replicated Borjas's scatter
diagram, and also his finding that unskilled natives suffer a loss
relative to, say, graduates. He made different assumptions, however,
about how businesses adjust to the influx of new workers, and as a
result, he found that the absolute harm was less, or the gain was
greater, for all native-born groups. By his reckoning, native dropouts
lost only 1 percent of their income during the 1990's.
Peri's theory is that most of the wage losses are sustained by previous
immigrants, because immigrants compete most directly with one another.
It's a principle of economics that a surplus in one part of the
production scheme raises the demand for every other one. For instance,
if you have a big influx of chefs, you can use more waiters, pushing up
their wages; if you have a lot of chefs and waiters, you need more
Sub-Zeros, so investment will also rise. The only ones hurt, in this
example, are the homegrown chefs -- the people who are "like" the
immigrants.
Indeed, workers who are unlike immigrants see a net gain; more foreign
doctors increases the demand for native hospital administrators. Borjas
assumes that a native dropout (or a native anything) is interchangeable
with an immigrant of the same skill level. Peri doesn't. If enough
Mexicans go into construction, some native workers may be hurt, but a
few will get promotions, because with more crews working there will be a
greater demand for foremen, who most likely will be natives.
Natives have a different mix of skills -- English, for instance, or
knowledge of the landscape. In economists' lingo, foreigners are not
"perfect substitutes." (Friedberg also observed this in Israel.) In some
cases, they will complement rather than compete with native workers.
Vietnamese manicurists in California cater to a lower-price,
less-exclusive market than native-run salons. The particular skills of
an Italian designer -- or even an economist -- are distinct from an
American's. "My work is autobiographical to a large extent," notes Peri,
who got into the field when the Italian government commissioned him to
study why Italy was losing so many professionals. The foreigners he sees
in California are a boon to the U.S. It astonishes him how people like
Sensenbrenner want to restrict
immigration and apply the letter of the law against those
working here.
This is a very romantic view. The issue is not so much Italian designers
as Mexican dropouts. But many Mexicans work jobs that are unappealing to
most Americans; in this sense, they are not exactly like natives of
their skill level either. Mexicans have replenished some occupations
that would have become underpopulated; for instance, 40,000 people who
became meat processors immigrated to the U.S. during the 1990's, shoring
up the industry. Without them, some plants would have raised wages, but
others would have closed or, indeed, relocated to Mexico.
$( Are All Dropouts the Same? $)
I talked to half a dozen vintners and a like number of roofing-company
owners, both fields that rely on Mexican labor, and frequently heard
that Americans do not, in sufficient numbers, want the work. In the case
of the vineyards, if Mexicans weren't available, some of the grapes
would be harvested by machine. This is what economists mean by "capital
adjusting." If the human skills are there, capital will find a way to
employ them. Over the short term, people chase jobs, but over the long
term jobs chase people. (That is why software firms locate in Silicon
Valley.)
If you talk to enough employers, you start to gather that they prefer
immigrant labor over unskilled Americans. The former have fewer problems
with tardiness, a better work ethic. Some of this may be prejudice. But
it's possible that Mexican dropouts may be better workers than our
dropouts. In Mexico, not finishing high school is the norm; it's not
associated with an unsuitability for work or even especially with
failure. In the U.S., where the great majority do graduate, those who
don't graduate have high rates of drug use and problems with the law.
The issue is charged because the group with by far the highest rate of
incarceration is African-American dropouts. Approximately 20 percent of
black males without high-school diplomas are in jail. Indeed, according
to Steven Raphael, a colleague of Card's at Berkeley, the correlation
between wages and immigration
is a lot weaker if you control for the fact that so many black men are
in prison. But should you control for it? Borjas says he thinks not.
It's pretty well established that as the reward for legal work
diminishes, some people turn to crime. This is why people sold crack;
the payoff was tremendous. Borjas has developed one of his graphs to
show that the presence of immigrants is correlated with doing time,
especially among African-Americans. Incarceration rates, he notes, rose
sharply in the 70's, just as
immigration did. He doesn't pretend that this is the whole
explanation -- only that there is a link. Card retorts: "The idea that
the way to help the lot of African-Americans is to restrict Mexicans is
ridiculous." Black leaders have themselves mostly switched sides. In the
20's, A. Philip Randolph, who led the Pullman Porters, spoke in favor of
immigration quotas, but
the civil rights establishment no longer treats
immigration as a big issue;
instead it tends to look at immigrants as potential constituents. (One
person who takes issue with the prevailing view is Anthony W. Williams,
an African-American pastor in Chicago who is running for Congress
against Representative Jesse Jackson Jr. Black leaders have forsaken
their mission, he told me. "Immigration
will destroy the economic base of the African-American community.")
In the spring, as the Senate Judiciary Committee was trying to parse
these issues into a piece of legislation, Borjas and Card were invited
to air their views. Each declined, in part because they don't think
politicians really listen. As if to prove the point, the effort to write
a joint bill has stalled, following Sensenbrenner's announcement that
the House intends to stage a series of public hearings on
immigration around the
country over the summer. There will be a lot said about border control,
many heartfelt stories and probably very little about natural
experiments.
The economists do have political opinions, of course. Borjas leans to a
system like Canada's, which would admit immigrants on the basis of
skills. He also says that, to make sure the problem of illegals does not
recur, the U.S. should secure its borders before it adjusts the status
of its present illegals.
Advocates of a more open policy often cite the country's history. They
argue that the racists of bygone eras were not only discriminatory but
also wrong. Card, for instance, mentioned an article penned by a future
U.S. senator, Paul Douglas, titled "Is the New
Immigration More Unskilled
Than the Old?" It was written in 1919, when many people (though not
Douglas) held that Jews, Slavs and Italians were incompatible with the
country's Anglo and Teutonic stock. Nativism has always been part of the
American scene, and it has tended to turn ugly in periods when the
country was tired of or suspicious of foreigners. In 1952, quotas were
maintained in a law sponsored by Senator Pat McCarran, a prominent
McCarthyite. There remains today a palpable strain of xenophobia in the
anti-immigrant movement. Dan Stein, president of the Federation for
American Immigration
Reform, remarked to me, rather meanly, "If someone comes here from China
and they go swimming in a dangerous river, a sign in English is enough,
but the Mexicans want it in Spanish." Ninety years ago, some signs were
in German, as were 500 newspapers on American soil.
But U.S. history, as Borjas observes, can be read in two ways. For sure,
earlier waves of immigrants assimilated, but America essentially closed
the gate for 40 years. Antipathy toward Germans during World War I
forced German-Americans to hide all traces of their origins. The quotas
of the 1920's were reinforced by the Depression and then by World War
II. The country had time to let assimilation occur.
A reverse process seems to be occurring with Mexican-Americans. Very few
Mexicans came north in the decades after 1920, even though they were
relatively free to do so. As recently as 1970, the U.S. had fewer than
one million Mexicans, almost all of them in Texas and California. The
U.S. did bring Mexican braceros to work on farms during the 1940's, 50's
and 60's. The program was terminated in 1964, and
immigration officials
immediately noticed a sharp rise in illicit border crossings. The
collapse of the Mexican economy in the 70's gave migrants a further
push. Finally, Mexicans who obtained legal status were (thanks to the
1965 reform) able to bring in family members.
The important point is that, ultimately, there was a catalytic effect --
so many Mexicans settled here that it became easier for more Mexicans to
follow. One story has it that in a village in central Mexico people knew
the price of mushrooms in Pennsylvania sooner than people in the next
county over. Even if apocryphal, it illustrates what economists call a
network effect: with 12 million people born in Mexico now dispersed
around the U.S., information about job-market conditions filters back to
Mexico with remarkable speed.
Now that the network is established, the exodus feels rather permanent;
it is not a wave but a continuous flow. This has led to understandable
anxiety, even among economists, about whether Mexicans will assimilate
as rapidly as previous groups. Although second-generation Mexicans do
(overwhelmingly) speak English, and also graduate from high school at
far higher rates than their parents, Borjas has documented what he calls
an ethnic "half-life" of immigrant groups: with each generation, members
of the group retain half of the income and educational deficit (or
advantage) of their parents. In other words, each group tends toward the
mean, but the process is slow. Last year he wrote that Mexicans in
America are burdened if not doomed by their "ethnic capital," and will
be for several generations. In "Heaven's Door," Borjas even wrote
forgivingly of the quota system enacted in the 20's, observing that it
"was not born out of thin air; it was the political consensus. .
.reached after 30 years of debate." These are distasteful words to many
people. But Borjas does not advocate a return to quotas. His point is
that Americans shouldn't kid themselves: "National origin and immigrant
skills are so intimately related, any attempt to change one will
inevitably change the other."
$( The Limits of Economics $)
Economists more in the mainstream generally agree that the U.S. should
take in more skilled immigrants; it's the issue of the unskilled that is
tricky. Many say that unskilled labor is needed and that the U.S. could
better help its native unskilled by other means (like raising the
minimum wage or expanding job training) than by building a wall. None
believe, however, that the U.S. can get by with no limits. Richard B.
Freeman of Harvard floated the idea that the U.S. simply sell visas at a
reasonable price. The fee could be adjusted according to indicators like
the unemployment rate. It is unlikely that Congress will go for anything
so cute, and the economists' specific prescriptions may be beside the
point. As they acknowledge,
immigration policy responds to a host of factors -- cultural,
political and social as well as economic. Migrant workers, sometimes
just by crowding an uncustomary allotment of people into a single
dwelling, bring a bit of disorder to our civic life; such concerns,
though beyond the economists' range, are properly part of the debate.
What the economists can do is frame a subset of the important issues.
They remind us, first, that the legislated goal of U.S. policy is
curiously disconnected from economics. Indeed, the flow of illegals is
the market's signal that the current legal limits are too low.
Immigrants do help the economy; they are fuel for growth cities like Las
Vegas and a salve to older cities that have suffered native flight.
Borjas's research strongly suggests that native unskilled workers pay a
price: in wages, in their ability to find inviting areas to migrate to
and perhaps in employment. But the price is probably a small one.
The disconnect between Borjas's results and Card's hints that there is
an alchemy that occurs when immigrants land ashore; the economy's
potential for absorbing and also adapting is mysterious but powerful.
Like any form of economic change,
immigration causes distress and disruption to some. But
America has always thrived on dynamic transformations that produce
winners as well as losers. Such transformations stimulate growth. Other
societies (like those in Europe) have opted for more controls, on
immigration and on labor
markets generally. They have more stability and more equality, but less
growth and fewer jobs. Economists have highlighted these issues, but
they cannot decide them. Their resolution depends on a question that
Card posed but that the public has not yet come to terms with: "What is
it that immigration policy
is supposed to achieve?"
Published on Wednesday, January 23, 2002 in the International Herald Tribune |
To Head Off Mass Migrations, Set a Global Minimum Wage |
by Michael Ardon |
|
JERUSALEM -- The fact that globalization is widening the gap between the rich North and the poor South, and is increasing poverty in many developing countries, is used to discredit the very idea of globalization. This is confused thinking. The term "globalization" is generally understood to mean the trend to enable a free flow of goods and capital by removing national and regional barriers. Such a definition is misleading, because it leaves out one of the most important elements of a truly competitive global economy - the free flow of work forces. Globalization, as practiced today, is based on fundamentally contradictory elements: a free flow of goods and capital, coupled with a ban on the free flow of work forces from country to country. Globalization based on maintaining restrictions on immigration is self-contradicting. The basic paradox of the current ideology of globalization is that without the freedom of laborers to work anywhere, free competition and the rule of market forces in the global economy are mere fictions. What is more, most of the negative results of globalization, as it is now practiced, originate from this restriction on the free flow of work forces. It is this restriction which maintains wages of less than a dollar a day in developing countries. It is this restriction which leads to the coexistence of very poor and very rich countries in the world of today. It is this restriction which nourishes feelings of hatred and revenge in poor countries toward the affluent North. But of course the North cannot afford to lift all restrictions on immigration, in the world as it is today. That would result in migration to the rich countries by hundreds of millions of poor laborers. Such population movements could be seriously disruptive. There is no rapid solution to the inherent contradiction between restricted immigration and globalization. The only long-term solution lies in bridging the gap between the per capita incomes in the rich and poor countries. Only when this income gap is narrowed will a global free flow of labor be possible without massive migration. People do not tend to leave their homelands for a differential increase in income. Language, cultural and social barriers, the high costs of migration and of finding alternative living quarters, all this tends to discourage people from leaving home unless they have to. Given the choice between $20 a day at home and $40 a day in a distant developed country, most people will choose to stay at home. Not so, though, if the choice is between staying at home hungry on $1 a day and emigrating to a developed country where a minimum wage and social benefits are secured. A reasonable gap in incomes between South and North that would minimize the drive to emigrate would have two positive results: • A 20-fold increase in wages in the South would eliminate hunger and extreme poverty for billions of people, and would simultaneously eliminate the global dangers that result from these conditions. • Foreign capital would continue to flow to the South, even if the ratio of labor costs between South and North were 1-to-2 instead of 1-to-40. But by what mechanism could such a substantial narrowing of the gap be achieved? One of the options is a comprehensive global minimum wage. The minimum wage might initially be only slightly higher than the present low wages in some developing countries, so as not to disrupt their economies, but it would be increased annually. Ultimately it should reach 40 to 50 percent of the average minimum wage in the industrialized nations. Compliance with such a minimum wage might be achieved by a ban on imports from countries that fail to adopt it. In the aftermath of Sept. 11, the time has come to realize that a deluxe globalization for the rich, without globalization of the labor force, is not sustainable, and that until some equity is attained between poor and rich countries, no true globalization will be achieved. Furthermore, if the gap between the two worlds is not narrowed, the poor countries will continue to breed forces that endanger the very existence of our civilization. The writer, a professor of chemistry at The Hebrew University in Jerusalem, contributed this comment to the International Herald Tribune. Copyright © 2002 the International Herald Tribune |
Published on Tuesday, May 9, 2006 by the Chicago Sun-Times |
|
Published on Saturday, May 20, 2006 by CommonDreams.org |
The Framing of Immigration |
by George Lakoff and Sam Ferguson |
|
On May 15th, in an address from the Oval Office, President Bush presented his proposal for “comprehensive immigration reform." The term “immigration reform” evokes an issue-defining conceptual frame — The Immigration Problem Frame — a frame that imposes a structure on the current situation, defines a set of “problems” with that situation, and circumscribes the possibility for “solutions.” “Reform,” when used in politics, indicates there is a pressing issue that needs to be addressed — take “medicare reform,” “lobbying reform,” “social security reform.” The noun that's attached to reform — “immigration” — points to where the problem lies. Whatever noun is attached to “reform” becomes the locus of the problem and constrains what counts as a solution. To illustrate, take “lobbying reform.” In the wake of the Jack Abramoff scandal, “lobbying reform” was all the talk in the media and on Capitol Hill. The problem defined by this frame has to do with lobbyists. As a “lobbyist” problem, the solutions focused on Congressional rules regarding lobbyists. The debate centered around compensated meals, compensated trips, access by former Congressmen (who inevitably become lobbyists) to the floor of the Senate and House of representatives, lobbying disclosure, lobbyists' access to Congressional staff and the period of time between leaving the Congress and becoming a registered lobbyists. Indeed, if the reform needed is “lobbying reform,” these are reasonable solutions. But, the term “Congressional ethics reform” would have framed a problem of a much different nature, a problem with Congressmen. And it would allow very different reforms to count as solutions. After all, lobbyists are powerless if there's nobody to accept a free meal, fly on a private plane, play a round of golf in the Bahamas and, most importantly, accept the political contributions lobbyists raise on their behalf from special-interests with billions of dollars in business before the federal Government. A solution could, for example, have been Full Public Financing of Elections and free airtime for political candidates as part of the licensing of the public's airwaves to private corporations. The “lobbying reform” framing of the issue precluded such considerations from discussion, because they don't count as solutions to the “lobbying” problem. Issue-defining frames are powerful. “Immigration reform” also evokes an issue-defining frame. Bush, in his speech, pointed out the problems that this frame defines. First, the Government has “not been in complete control of its borders.” Second, millions are able to “sneak across our border” seeking to make money. Finally, once here, illegal immigrants sometimes forge documents to get work, skirting labor laws, and deceiving employers who attempt to follow the law. They may take jobs away from legal immigrants and ordinary Americans, bear children who will be American citizens even in they are not, and use local services like schools and hospitals, which may cost a local government a great deal. This is his definition of the problem in the Immigration Reform frame. This definition of the problem focuses entirely on the immigrants and the administrative agencies charged with overseeing immigration law. The reason is that these are the only roles present in the Immigration Problem Frame. Bush's “comprehensive solution” entirely concerns the immigrants, citizenship laws, and the border patrol. And, from the narrow problem identified by framing it as an “immigration problem,” Bush's solution is comprehensive. He has at least addressed everything that counts as a problem in the immigration frame. But the real problem with the current situation runs broader and deeper. Consider the issue of Foreign Policy Reform, which focuses on two sub-issues:
Such a framing of the problem would lead to a solution involving the Secretary of State, conversations with Mexico and other Central American countries, and a close examination of the promises of NAFTA, CAFTA, the WTO, the IMF and the World Bank to raise standards of living around the globe. It would inject into the globalization debate a concern for the migration and displacement of people, not simply globalization's promise for profits. This is not addressed when the issue is defined as the “immigration problem.” Bush's “comprehensive solution” does not address any of these concerns. The immigration problem, in this light, is actually a globalization problem. Perhaps the problem might be better understood as a humanitarian crisis. Can the mass migration and displacement of people from their homelands at a rate of 800,000 people a year be understood as anything else? Unknown numbers of people have died trekking through the extreme conditions of the Arizona and New Mexico desert. Towns are being depopulated and ways of life lost in rural Mexico. Fathers feel forced to leave their families in their best attempt to provide for their kids. Everyday, boatloads of people arrive on our shores after miserable journeys at sea in deplorable conditions. As a humanitarian crisis, the solution could involve The UN or the Organization of American States. But these bodies do not have roles in the immigration frame, so they have no place in an “immigration debate.” Framing this as just an “immigration problem” prevents us from penetrating deeper into the issue. The current situation can also be seen as a civil rights problem. The millions of people living here who crossed illegally are for most intents and purposes Americans. They work here. They pay taxes here. Their kids are in school here. They plan to raise their families here. For the most part, they are assimilated into the American system, but are forced to live underground and in the shadows because of their legal status. They are denied ordinary civil rights. The “immigration problem” framing overlooks their basic human dignity. Perhaps most pointedly, the “immigration problem” frame blocks an understanding of this issue as a cheap labor issue. The undocumented immigrants allow employers to pay low wages, which in turn provide the cheap consumer goods we find at WalMart and McDonalds. They are part of a move towards the cheap lifestyle, where employers and consumers find any way they can to save a dollar, regardless of the human cost. Most of us partake in this cheap lifestyle, and as a consequence, we are all complicit in the current problematic situation. Business, Consumers and Government have turned a blind eye to the problem for so long because our entire economy is structured around subsistence wages. Americans won't do the work immigrants do not because they don't want to, but because they won't do it for such low pay. Since Bush was elected, corporate profits have doubled but there has been no increase in wages. This is really a wage problem. The workers who are being more productive are not getting paid for their increased productivity. A solution to the “immigration problem” will not address these concerns because they are absent from the “immigration frame.” Framing matters. The notion of this as “an immigration problem” needing “immigration reform” is not neutral. Surface Framing We now turn from conceptual framing of the current situation to the words used and surface frames those words evoke. The Illegal Frame The Illegal Frame is perhaps the most commonly used frame within the immigration debate. Journalists frequently refer to “illegal immigrants” as if it were a neutral term. But the illegal frame is highly structured. It frames the problem as one about the illegal act of crossing the border without papers. As a consequence, it fundamentally frames the problem as a legal one. Think for a moment of a criminal. Chances are you thought about a robber, a murderer or a rapist. These are prototypical criminals, people who do harm to a person or their property. And prototypical criminals are assumed to be bad people. “Illegal,” used as an adjective in “illegal immigrants” and “illegal aliens,” or simply as a noun in “illegals” defines the immigrants as criminals, as if they were inherently bad people. In conservative doctrine, those who break laws must be punished — or all law and order will break down. Failure to punish is immoral. “Illegal alien” not only stresses criminality, but stresses otherness. As we are a nation of immigrants, we can at least empathize with immigrants, illegal or not. “Aliens,” in popular culture suggests nonhuman beings invading from outer space — completely foreign, not one of us, intent on taking over our land and our way of life by gradually insinuating themselves among us. Along these lines, the word “invasion” is used by the Minutemen and right-wing bloggers to discuss the wave of people crossing the border. Right-wing language experts intent on keep them out suggest using the world “aliens” whenever possible. These are NOT neutral terms. Imagine calling businessmen who once cheated on their taxes “illegal businessmen.” Imagine calling people who have driven over the speed limit “illegal drivers.” Is Tom Delay an “illegal Republican?” By defining them as criminal, it overlooks the immense contributions these immigrants subsequently make by working hard for low wages. This is work that should more than make up for crossing the border. Indeed, we should be expressing our gratitude. Immigrants who cross outside of legal channels, though, are committing offenses of a much different nature than the prototypical criminal. Their intent is not to cause harm or to steal. More accurately, they are committing victimless technical offenses, which we normally consider “violations.” By invoking the illegal frame, the severity of their offense is inflated. The illegal frame — particularly “illegal alien” — dehumanizes. It blocks the questions of: why are people coming to the US, often times at great personal risk? What service do they provide when they are here? Why do they feel it necessary to avoid legal channels? It boils the entire debate down to questions of legality. And it also ignores the illegal acts of employers. The problem is not being called the Illegal Employer Problem, and employers are not called “illegals. The Security Frame The logical response to the “wave” of “illegal immigration” becomes “border security.” The Government has a responsibility to provide security for its citizens from criminals and invaders. President Bush has asked to place the National Guard on the border to provide security. Indeed, he referred to “security” six times in his immigration speech. Additionally, Congress recently appropriated money from the so-called “war on terror” for border security with Mexico. This should outrage the American public. How could Congress conflate the war on terror with illegal immigration? Terrorists come to destroy the American dream, immigrants — both documented and undocumented — come to live the American dream. But the conceptual move from illegal immigrant (criminal, evil), to border security to a front of the war on terror, an ever expanding war against evil in all places and all times wherever it is, is not far. It is this understanding of the issue that also prompted the House to pass the punitive HR 4437, which includes a provision to make assisting illegal immigrants while they are here a felony. It is seen as aiding and abetting a criminal. But how could this be a “security” issue? Security implies that there is a threat, and a threatened, and that the threatened needs protection. These immigrants are not a physical threat, they are a vital part of our economy and help America function. They don't want to shoot us or kill us or blow us up. They only want to weed our gardens, clean our houses, and cook our meals in search of the American Dream. They must be recognized as Americans making a vital impact and contribution. And when they are, we will cease to tolerate the substandard conditions in which they are forced to work and live. No American — indeed, no person — should be treated so brashly. Amnesty “Amnesty” also fits the Illegal Frame. Amnesty is a pardoning of an illegal action — a show of either benevolence or mercy by a supreme power. It implies that the fault lies with the immigrants, and it is a righteous act for the US Government to pardon them. This again blocks the reality that Government looks the other way, and Business has gone much further — it has been a full partner in creating the current situation. If amnesty is to be granted, it seems that amnesty should be given to the businesses who knowingly or unknowingly hired the immigrants and to the Government for turning a blind eye. But amnesty to these parties is not considered, because it's an “immigration problem.” Business has no role in this frame, and Government can't be given amnesty for not enforcing its own laws. The Undocumented Worker Frame By comparison, the term “undocumented worker” activates a conceptual frame that seems less accusatory and more compassionate than the “illegal” frame. But a closer look reveals fundamental problems with this framing. First, the negative “undocumented” suggests that they should be documented - that there is something wrong with them if they are not. Second, “worker” suggests that their function in America is only to work, not to be educated, have families, form communities, have lives — and vote! This term was suggested by supporters of the immigrants as less noxious than illegal aliens, and it is, but it has serious limitations. It accepts the framing of immigrants as being here only to work. Temporary Workers “Undocumented workers” opened the door to Bush's new proposal for “temporary workers,” who come to America for a short time, work for low wages, do not vote, have few rights and services, and then go home so that a new wave of workers without rights, or the possibility of citizenship and voting, can come in. This is thoroughly undemocratic and serves the financial and electoral interests of conservatives. This term replaced “guest worker,” which was ridiculed. Imagine inviting some to dinner as a guest and then asking him to pick the vegetables, cook the dinner, and wash the dishes! Frames Not Taken Most of the framing initiative has been taken by conservatives. Progressives have so far abstained. Progressives could well frame the situation as the Cheap Labor Issue or the Cheap Lifestyle Issue. Most corporations use the common economic metaphor of labor as a resource. There are two kinds of employees — the Assets (creative people and managers) and Resources (who are relatively unskilled, fungible, interchangeable). The American economy is structured to drive down the cost of resources - that is, the wages of low-skilled, replaceable workers. Immigration increases the supply of such workers and helps to drive down wages. Cheap labor increases “productivity” and profits for employers, and it permits a cheap lifestyle for consumers who get low prices because of cheap labor. But these are not seen as “problems.” They are benefits. And people take these benefits for granted. They are not grateful to the immigrants who make them possible. Gratitude. The word is hardly ever spoken in the discourse over immigration. Now consider the frame defined by the term “economic refugee.” A refugee is a person who has fled their homeland, due to political or social strife, and seeks asylum in another country. An economic refugee would extend this category (metaphorically, not legally, though it might be shifted legally in the future) to include people fleeing their homeland as a result of economic insecurity. Refugees are worthy of compassion. We should accept them into our nation. All people are entitled to a stable political community where they have reasonable life prospects to lead a fulfilling life — this is the essence of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights. To frame the debate this way is to advance a progressive understanding. While immigrants are here, they should be integrated into society either temporarily, if conditions improve in their home country, or permanently, if they can integrate and become productive members of our nation. It will focus solutions on US foreign policy to be about people, not profits. The only way the migration of people from the South to the North will stop is when conditions are improved there. As long as there is a pull to the North and a push from the South, people will find their way over, no matter how big, how long or how guarded a border fence is. (As an aside, who will build that fence if all the undocumented immigrants leave?) Increased security will force people to find ever more dangerous crossings, as has already happened, without slowing the flow of immigrants. More people will die unnecessarily. Even if we could “protect” ourselves by sealing the border and preventing businesses from hiring undocumented immigrants by imposing hefty fines or prison sentences for violations, progressives should not be satisfied. This still leaves those yearning to flee their own countries in search of a better life in deplorable situations. The problem is not dealt with by making the United States a gated community. While these refugees are here, they must be treated with dignity and respect. Indeed, if they cannot return home, we have a responsibility to welcome them into ours. And we must treat them as Americans, not as second-class citizens, as they are currently. If they are here, they work hard and contribute to society, they are worthy of a path to citizenship and the basic rights we are entitled to (a minimum wage, education, healthcare, a social safety net). Currently, the undocumented immigrants living amongst us are un-enfranchised workers. They perform all the work, pay all the duties, and receive many fewer of the benefits — especially voting rights. They must be given an opportunity to come out of the shadows and lead normal lives as Americans. The answer to this problem isn't an “open-border.” The United States cannot take on the world's problems on its own. Other affluent countries need to extend a humanitarian arm to peoples fleeing oppressive economic circumstances as well. How many immigrants the United States should be willing to accept will ultimately be up to Congress. In presenting these alternative frames, we want to inject humanitarian concerns based in compassion and empathy into the debate. The problem is dealing adequately with a humanitarian crisis that extends well beyond the southern border. The focus must shift from the immigrants themselves and domestic policy to a broader view of why so many people flee, and how we can help alleviate conditions in Mexico and Central America to prevent the flow in the first place. Only by reframing of the debate can we incorporate more global considerations. Immigration crises only arise from global disparity. Why It's Not a Single Issue The wealth of frames in this debate has made it confusing. The frames within the debate have been divisive. But the absence of frames to counter the idea of the “immigration problem” has also been divisive. Since each frame presents a different component of the problem, it's worth noting who stresses which frames, and which problems that frame define. Conservatives
Law and Order: The “illegal immigrants” are criminals, felons, and must be punished - rounded up and sent home. There should be no amnesty. Otherwise all law will break down. The Nativists: The immigrants are diluting our culture, our language, and our values. The Profiteers: We need cheap labor to keep our profits up and our cheap lifestyle in place. The Bean Counters: We can't afford to have illegal immigrants using our tax dollars on health, education, and other services. The Security Hounds: We need more border guards and a hi-tech wall to guarantee our security. Progressives Progressivism Begins at Home: The immigrants are taking the jobs of American works and we have to protect our workers. African-American Protectionists: Hispanic immigrants are threatening African-American jobs. Provide a path to citizenship: The immigrants have earned citizenship with their hard work, their devotion to American values, and their contribution to our society. Foreign Policy Reformers: We need to pay attention to the causes that drive others from their homelands. Wage supports: Institute a serious earned income tax credit for Americans doing otherwise low-paying jobs, so that more Americans will want to do them and fewer immigrants will be drawn here. Illegal Employers: The way to protect American workers and slow immigration of unskilled workers is to prosecute employers of unskilled workers. We can see why this is such a complex problem and why there are so splits within both the conservative and progressive ranks. Summing Up The “immigration issue” is anything but. It is a complex melange of social, economic, cultural and security concerns — with conservatives and progressives split in different ways with different positions. Framing the recent problem as an “immigration problem” pre-empts many of these considerations from entering the debate. As a consequence, any reform that “solves” the immigration problem is bound to be a patchwork solution addressing bits and pieces of much larger concerns. Bush's comprehensive reform is comprehensive, but only for the narrow set of problems defined in the “immigration debate.” It does not address many of the questions with which progressives should be primarily concerned, issues of basic experiential well-being and political rights. Ultimately, the way the current immigration debate is going — focusing narrowly on domestic policy, executive agencies and the immigrants — we will be faced with the same problems 10 years from now. The same long lines of immigrants waiting for legal status will persist. Temporary workers will not return home after their visas have expired, and millions of undocumented people will live amongst us. Only by broadening the understanding of the situation will the problem, or, rather, the multiple problems, be addressed and adequately solved. The immigration problem does not sit in isolation from other problems, but is symptomatic of broader social and economic concerns. The framing of the “immigration problem” must not pre-empt us from debating and beginning to address these broader concerns. © 2006 The Rockridge Institute ### |
And from the backwater where I grew up, these items of note (from the Arizona Republic):
Feb. 8, 2007 12:00 AM
Sheriff Joe Arpaio received the Maricopa
County Board of Supervisors' blessing on Wednesday to train up to 160
officers to enforce federal immigration laws.
Arpaio said the officers will be used to arrest suspected undocumented
immigrants and turn them over to the federal government.
A small but growing number of law enforcement officials in the
United States have asked for similar training. Critics contend
that local officers doubling as immigration agents could undermine
public safety by making immigrants reluctant to report crimes and could
lead to racial profiling.
|
|
|
|
|
Federal officials could finalize the agreement within days, with the
hope of starting the four- to five-week training for the first group on
Feb. 27.
- Daniel González
The
Sins of the Fathers:
The Children of Undocumented Immigrants Pay the Price
by Alfredo Gutierrez*
For the undocumented in America there is little doubt that the iniquities of the father are visited upon the child. On November 7th, for instance, an astounding 71 percent of voters in Arizona passed a referendum (Proposition 300) which states that only U.S. citizens and legal residents are eligible for in-state college tuition rates, tuition and fee waivers, and financial assistance. These are kids brought by their parents to this country as young children, in many instances infants in their mothers’ arms, and in every instance as children for whom the decision to come here was made without their participation. And yet, they shall pay the price, perhaps with their futures. The same referendum would deny childcare to the U.S.-citizen children of undocumented parents. Yes, the child is a citizen of the United States, but voters in Arizona have concluded that to provide the child with care is to reward the parents for the sin of seeking a better life in America.
Even without new measures such as Proposition 300, undocumented children already live precarious lives in the United States. Take the “Wilson Four,” for example. In 2002, a group of students from Wilson Charter High School in Phoenix who won an international science competition were rewarded with a visit to Niagara Falls. As an appeals court recently concluded, they were subjected to illegal racial profiling when, at the Canadian border, U.S. immigration officials detained and initiated deportation proceedings against them. Interestingly, one of the Wilson Four dreams of joining the U.S. Army, becoming a Ranger, and defending this country. But he will be unable to do so as long as he lacks legal status.
The Development, Relief, and Education for Alien Minors (DREAM) Act—which was made part of the Comprehensive Immigration Reform Act of 2006 passed by the Senate last year—would remedy this injustice. The bill would offer a pathway to conditional legal status for unauthorized youth who arrived in the United States before age 16, have been here for five years, and have graduated from high school or obtained a GED. Those who obtain conditional legal status would be eligible for permanent legal status—and, five years after that, U.S. citizenship—if they attend college or join the military. Moreover, the bill would allow states to offer these students in-state tuition rates. A report by the Migration Policy Institute estimates that, if the DREAM Act were passed, 360,000 unauthorized high-school graduates age 18 to 24 would immediately become eligible for conditional legal status and about 715,000 more unauthorized youth age 5 to 17 would become eligible in the future.1
The DREAM Act has been debated for a decade. And for a decade opponents of the bill who argue that the Dream Act rewards the illegal acts of the father have won. There is, of course, a perverse logic to this argument. To absolve the child of the taint of a crime that the child did not commit is to give advantage to the one who did. Denying justice to the innocent child is, therefore, a way to extract punishment by proxy from the guilty parent. The children are undocumented, after all, and when they reach the age of majority—so the argument goes—we should complete the fiction and legally define them as if they had knowingly committed the crime.
I believe that the most effective, immediate step we can take to lower the drop-out rate in the Hispanic community is to pass the DREAM Act and let kids and their parents have hope, let them dream, and let them become their dreams. This is not idle chatter. Since passage of Proposition 300 in Arizona I have attended dozens of meetings with affected college students and their parents. I have met with kids well on their way to becoming teachers, doctors, counselors, scientists, and every other kind of profession conceivable. Many students such as these will permanently drop out of school. Many of them say they will abandon their studies for a year, until the DREAM Act passes, after which they intend to return. I believe their hopes to be well grounded. I pray their hopes are well grounded.
Now that a new congress has arrived in Washington, there finally is hope that justice will prevail. Congress cannot avoid the reality of these kids any longer. Only Congress can and must decide on behalf of hundreds of thousands of children whether or not federal law will continue to visit the sins of the father upon the children.
A Humanitarian Crisis at the Border:
New
Estimates of Deaths Among Unauthorized Immigrants
By Raquel Rubio-Goldsmith, M. Melissa McCormick, Daniel Martinez & Inez
Magdalena Duarte*
For almost a decade now, there has been an unprecedented increase in the number of deaths each year among unauthorized border-crossers in the deserts and mountains of southern Arizona. The official statistics compiled by the U.S. Border Patrol consistently undercount the actual number of deaths in Arizona and elsewhere along the U.S.-Mexico border. But various academic and government studies estimate that the bodies of between 2,000 and 3,000 men, women, and children have been found along the entire southwest border since 1995, including at least 1,000 in the inhospitable terrain of southern Arizona. Experts, including the U.S. Government Accountability Office (GAO), now explain this crisis as a direct consequence of U.S. immigration-control policies instituted in the mid-1990s.1
The Binational Migration Institute (BMI) of the University of Arizona’s Mexican American Studies and Research Center has undertaken a unique and scientifically rigorous study of all unauthorized border-crosser (UBC) deaths examined by the Pima County Medical Examiner’s Office (PCMEO) from 1990-2005.2 [Read the complete BMI study] Because the PCMEO has handled approximately 90 percent of all UBC recovered bodies in the U.S. Border Patrol’s Tucson Sector, an analysis of such deaths serves as an accurate reflection of the major characteristics of all known unauthorized border-crosser deaths that have occurred in this sector since 1990.
A reliable analysis of known deaths among unauthorized border-crossers in the Tucson Sector is important for many reasons. Most important is the fact that, according to available figures produced by the U.S. government and the academic community, a comparison of the totals of such deaths for each of the nine Border Patrol sectors along the U.S.-Mexico border shows that the Tucson Sector has been the site of the vast majority of known UBC deaths in the new millennium. The results of the BMI study, which are confirmed by comparable research, show that there has been a dramatic increase in the number of UBC recovered bodies in the Tucson Sector from 1990 to 2005, thereby creating a major public health and humanitarian crisis in the deserts of Arizona.
The “Funnel Effect”
In the mid-1990s, the U.S. government implemented a “prevention through deterrence” approach to immigration control that has resulted in the militarization of the border and a quintupling of border-enforcement expenditures. However, the new border barriers, fortified checkpoints, high-tech forms of surveillance, and thousands of additional Border Patrol agents stationed along the southwest border have not decreased the number of unauthorized migrants crossing into the United States. Rather, the new strategy has closed off major urban points of unauthorized migration in Texas and California and funneled hundreds of thousands of unauthorized migrants through southern Arizona’s remote and notoriously inhospitable deserts and mountains.3
The BMI study was designed specifically to measure this “funnel effect” created by U.S. immigration-control policies. The BMI study found that there has been an exponential increase in the number of UBC recovered bodies handled by the PCMEO from 1990 to 2005 {Figure 1}. Over this period of time, the PCMEO has examined the bodies of 927 unauthorized border-crossers, which, according to the GAO, account for at least 78 percent of the unprecedented increase in known UBC deaths along the entire southwest border of the United States from 1990-2003.4
BMI’s findings unambiguously confirm previous evidence that U.S. border-enforcement policies did create the funnel effect and that it is indeed the primary structural cause of death for thousands of unauthorized men, women, and children from Mexico, Central America, and South America who have tried to enter the United States. During the “pre-funnel effect” years (1990-1999), the PCMEO handled, on average, approximately 14 UBC recovered bodies per year. In stark contrast, during the funnel effect years (2000-2005), on average, 160 UBC recovered bodies were sent to the PCMEO each year. Over 80 percent of the unauthorized border-crosser bodies handled by the PCMEO have been under the age of 40, and there is a discernable, upward trend in the number of dead youth under the age of 18. There also has been a statistically significant decrease in the number of recovered bodies of unauthorized border-crossers from northern Mexico and a significant increase in the number of such decedents from central and southern Mexico.
A Humanitarian Crisis
The rising number of unauthorized border-crosser deaths along the U.S.-Mexico border coinciding with intensified militarization and fortification of the border has long been decried by national and international human rights and humanitarian-aid groups, among others. In the summer of 2006, then-Senate Majority Leader Bill Frist (R-TN) referred to it as a “humanitarian crisis.” Researchers at the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) have concluded that it is “emerging as a major public health issue.”6
Professor Wayne Cornelius, a leading scholar of immigration issues at the University of California, San Diego, estimates that the bodies of 2,978 unauthorized border crossers were recovered on U.S. soil from 1995-2004.7 Cornelius describes the body count in these terms: “To put this death toll in perspective, the fortified US border with Mexico has been more than 10 times deadlier to migrants from Mexico during the past nine years than the Berlin Wall was to East Germans throughout its 28-year existence.”8 And there is no indication that the massive amount of suffering and death along the U.S.-Mexico border will come to an end any time soon. According to the GAO, for instance, there were more deaths along the border in the first 9 months of 2006 (291) than in the first 9 months of 2005 (241).9
Primarily due to methodological limitations, however, previous research does not provide a fine-grained portrayal of such deaths in Arizona or elsewhere. Furthermore, other studies were not specifically designed to test the structural correlation between the funnel effect created by U.S. immigration-control policies and the increase in known migrant deaths in Arizona. No previous research focuses on the UBC recovered bodies processed by the overburdened PCMEO, which is conservatively estimated to have handled more than 90 percent of all the recovered bodies of unauthorized border crossers in the Border Patrol’s Tucson Sector, the site of the vast majority of such known deaths since 1995.10
Border Deaths are Undercounted
Of all the published counts of unauthorized border-crosser bodies recovered across the U.S.-Mexico border, official U.S. Border Patrol figures are the least inclusive, resulting in the smallest reported totals year after year. A GAO comparison of yearly totals from 2002-2005 produced by PCMEO and the Border Patrol for all known UBC deaths occurring in Pima County, Arizona, reveals serious discrepancies. In the GAO’s estimation, the Border Patrol undercounted known deaths in 2002 by 44 (32 percent), in 2003 by 56 (43 percent), and in 2004 by 46 (35.4 percent). According to the GAO, when the Border Patrol started to more fully integrate PCMEO data in 2005, they only undercounted known UBC deaths in Pima County by 1.11 However, the GAO’s finding for 2005 is questionable. A review of medical-examiner records by the Arizona Daily Star, for instance, produced an estimate of UBC deaths for all of Arizona in 2005 (221) that was significantly higher than the Border Patrol’s total count for the state (172).12
The inaccuracy of Border Patrol figures appears to be primarily a consequence of a very narrow set of criteria for classifying a death as a UBC death. In general, a death is included in the Border Patrol count only if it: 1) occurs during the furtherance of an illegal entry; 2) occurs within the Border Safety Initiative (BSI) “target zone” (which includes 45 counties on or near the U.S.-Mexico border—or 9 of the 20 Border Patrol sectors); and 3) occurs outside of the BSI target zone, but the Border Patrol was directly involved in the case.
Each of these criteria necessarily results in an undercount of known UBC deaths. First, determining when an unauthorized border-crosser has reached his or her destination and is no longer in furtherance of an illegal entry can be very difficult to ascertain. It can actually take some unauthorized migrants many months and many stopovers in various places before they reach their final destinations. Some even take on short-term employment in one location—as agricultural workers, for instance—before settling in another location. This limitation also excludes unauthorized migrants who reside in the United States, but who still, on occasion, travel back and forth across the U.S.-Mexico border.
Second, the Border Patrol also omits known UBC deaths by restricting their count to cases occurring within the BSI target zone or those in which the Border Patrol has been directly involved. As a result, for example, many of the UBC bodies recovered by tribal officials on Tohono O’odham lands southwest of Tucson have not been counted by the Border Patrol. It has been estimated that almost two-thirds of Arizona’s crossing fatalities in 2002 occurred within the boundaries of the Connecticut-sized reservation of the Tohono O’odham nation.13
Serious researchers who attempt to estimate the number of unauthorized border crossers who have died point out that the actual number of migrant deaths is, at present, unknowable. Most assume that there are actually far more deaths than have been discovered, especially given the relative invisibility and covert circumstances of deaths that occur in the remote, inhospitable areas. The Border Patrol, on the other hand, suggests that most UBC deaths ultimately are discovered. However, the Border Patrol’s logic regarding this issue is problematic given the history of its own counts.
The BMI Study
As a step towards improving the accuracy of available data on unauthorized border-crosser deaths, BMI has undertaken an analysis of computerized and hardcopy autopsy reports recorded by the PCMEO. To the best of our knowledge, the BMI study is the first in-depth analysis of autopsy reports produced by a medical examiner’s office over a long enough period of time (1990-2005) to allow a scientific assessment of how the nature and character of such deaths have changed since the implementation of prevention-through-deterrence border-enforcement policies in the mid-1990s.
BMI classified a decedent as an unauthorized border-crosser if he or she met a convincing combination of some or all of the following criteria as established by various authorities: lacked a U.S. Social Security number, lacked a permanent U.S. place of residence, Hispanic ethnicity, foreign-born, foreign nationality, foreign residency, foreign next of kin, died while in transit from Mexico to a destination in the United States, body located in a well-known migrant corridor or found with or reported by other unauthorized border-crossers, lacked a lawful U.S. immigration status, and/or possessed personal effects or documents typical of an unauthorized border-crosser (e.g., water jugs, U.S. or foreign currency, hygiene products, extra clothing, phone cards, phone numbers or addresses of contacts in a foreign country, a backpack).
Research and Reform
Until research along the lines of the BMI study is conducted elsewhere along the U.S.-Mexico border, our knowledge of the full impact of the funnel effect will be incomplete. Moreover, available statistics will continue to significantly underestimate the number of fatalities correlated with U.S. immigration-control practices along the border. The Border Patrol in particular needs to expand its criteria for classifying UBC recovered bodies. The current criteria exclude many known deaths along the border as well as in the U.S. interior.
Unauthorized migration into the United States is the result of many factors: modern-day forces of globalization, economic disparities, binational economic arrangements between the United States and Mexico such as NAFTA, and the long, complicated historical relationship between theses two adjacent nations. Nonetheless, U.S. immigration-control policies clearly play a significant role in determining the places where unauthorized border crossers attempt to enter the country. According to Border Patrol statistics, for instance, in 1991, prior to the start of prevention-through-deterrence immigration-control operations, only 1 out of every 19 Border Patrol apprehensions occurred in the Tucson Sector. By 2004, in contrast, Tucson accounted for 1 out of every 2.36 apprehensions.14
The best chance of reducing the number of unauthorized border-crossers entering the United States does not lie with misconceived border-control measures. Many years worth of research now makes it perfectly clear that the underlying logic of the current border-enforcement system is to eventually scare off would-be unauthorized border crossers via seemingly predictable, if unacceptable, levels of injury, suffering, and death for those who dare try. Rather, the solution is comprehensive immigration reform rooted in an honest assessment of the role of migrant labor in the United States as well as the forces of globalization in North America, Central America, and South America.
* Raquel Rubio-Goldsmith is Coordinator of the Binational Migration Institute (BMI) at the University of Arizona’s Mexican American Studies and Research Center and a Lecturer in the Department of Mexican-American Studies. M. Melissa McCormick is BMI Senior Research Specialist. In 2006, Daniel Martinez and Inez Magdalena Duarte were graduate students in MASRC and BMI research assistants.
And the Winner Is … Immigration reform on the killing floor By David Bacon Issue Date: 11.10.05
Hiding from the U.S. border patrol in an air-conditioning duct for nine and a half hours, Jorge Mendez couldn’t even come down to urinate. As agents passed below, he had to keep from making the slightest noise. “I thought about my wife and my family,” he remembers.
“I had filled out my application to get all of them documents. I thought of all of my hopes and dreams ending there. From the moment I saw the migra, I thought, ‘Everything is over.’” Miraculously, the agents left without finding him. “Thank God I escaped,” Mendez says fervently.
Unlike 212 of his 900 co-workers, Mendez had narrowly escaped one of the most infamous immigration raids in modern U.S. history: the enforcement action at Nebraska Beef on December 5, 2000. That day, federal agents (known as la migra to workers who live in fear of them) swooped down on the big Omaha meatpacking plant. They picked up three managers and three labor recruiters, accusing them of conspiring to bring workers up from Mexico and supplying them with false documents.
In bloodstained work clothes, the immigrant laborers were shackled like criminals and packed into buses. Many Omaha children didn’t see their fathers or mothers come home that night. Instead, their parents were driven hundreds of miles to the border and dumped on the other side.
For more than a decade, Omaha has been a testing ground for the enforcement of U.S. immigration policy, in large part because the city, and the small towns of Nebraska and Iowa that surround it, are ground zero for the meatpacking industry. Its labor needs are shaping the debate in Congress, which will determine who benefits from the country’s immigration laws.
To justify the raid, the Immigration and Naturalization Service (INS) said it had evidence that a Nebraska Beef recruiter in Mexico was offering jobs at $8.50 an hour, a $100 signing bonus, free housing, and fake Social Security cards. But the agency deported the very people who could have testified about how they were hired, so a federal judge dismissed the charges in April 2002. The company walked.
The workers left behind were not so fortunate. The deportations heightened a climate of fear inside the plant -- already a fact of life for those without papers. People fear not just raids but the consequences of losing their jobs. Employer sanctions, a provision of the Immigration Reform and Control Act of 1986, make holding a job a crime for an undocumented worker. “You have to keep working because if you lose that job, finding another is difficult,” Mendez explains.
After the raid, the plant’s production-line speed increased to make up for the missing workers -- beyond the normal rate of 2,400 cows a day, or one killed and cut apart every 24 seconds. Seven workers demanded a raise to compensate; they were fired. Many remaining workers tried to organize a union, but the fear was too strong. When the union election took place just months afterward, the United Food and Commercial Workers initiative lost, 452 to 345.
The raid wasn’t Nebraska Beef’s first experience with employer sanctions. For an entire year in 1998, the INS went through the employment records of every meatpacking plant in the state of Nebraska, plus two counties next door in Iowa, in what the agency called Operation Vanguard. Soon, more than 3,500 people had left their jobs, whether for immigration reasons or due to normal turnover. More than 300 people quit at Nebraska Beef alone.
After Operation Vanguard, Nebraska Governor (now U.S. Agriculture Secretary) Mike Johanns, employers, and the American Meat Institute (AMI) accused the INS of creating production bottlenecks, implying that they had been denied a necessary source of labor. Within six months, however, the meatpacking workforce had returned to previous levels. Omaha has earned a reputation as a place where people can find work, and they come -- from Mexico and Central America and barrios across the United States -- looking for it.
Immigration authorities (now Immigration and Customs Enforcement, or ICE) commonly defend sanctions by arguing that they discourage workers from coming to the United States illegally and free up jobs for citizens and legal residents, especially in communities with high unemployment. To press this point, immigration officials often accompany the media to a local unemployment office after a raid and post the jobs that supposedly have been vacated.
In fact, however, the number of people coming to the United States did not diminish with increased enforcement. According to the Census Bureau and the Pew Hispanic Center, there are more than 10.3 million undocumented residents in the country, an increase from 8.4 million in 2000. They estimate that the number has increased at 485,000 yearly -- the description of a steady social process rather than a failure by immigration authorities. Internationally, more than 175 million people now live outside the countries where they were born. They are overwhelmingly moving from poorer to richer countries. It’s unrealistic to expect workplace raids to deflect such an enormous global movement of people.
And the enforcement crackdown didn’t produce jobs for anyone else, either. The communities in Omaha that used to provide workers for the meatpacking plants, and that no longer do today, have seen almost no effect from immigration enforcement.
There have long been Mexicans and Latinos in Omaha. Immigrants have populated the city’s working-class neighborhoods for more than a century, comprising 22 percent of the population as early as 1900. Today they represent 26 percent. Over the last three decades, however, meatpacking has moved from plants in urban centers like Omaha and Chicago to small towns closer to where livestock are raised. Nebraska’s Latino population nearly doubled (95 percent) from 1990 to 2005 due to increases in these meatpacking towns within a few hours’ radius.
In the late 1960s, Omaha’s three largest plants closed, costing the jobs of more than 10,000 workers. The city’s black community had fought hard to pull down the color line in these plants in the 1930s and ’40s. The jobs provided not just economic stability but political power. In the ’50s, black members used their hard-won base in the United Packinghouse Workers to demand that bars, restaurants, and other establishments halt segregationist restrictions. In the McCarthyite hysteria of the time, blacks and their allies were labeled “Reds” by conservative local union leaders.
Then came the closures, devastating Omaha’s African American neighborhoods. Although other plants eventually took their places -- Nebraska Beef, Northern States Beef (now Swift), and Greater Omaha Packing Company -- the percentage of African American workers remains tiny. Immigration raids and Operation Vanguard didn’t create a single job for north Omaha’s black neighborhoods. Instead, packers relied on recruiting labor from farther and farther away, driven by a desire to keep labor costs low.
Meatpacking wages have steadily fallen behind the manufacturing average. According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1980 slaughtering-plant wages were 1.16 times the manufacturing average. After nearly 25 years, they are now 0.76 times that average (or an hourly $11.59 in 2003). Considering how hard and dirty a slaughterhouse job can get, that wage is not a great attraction to any native-born or longtime-resident worker who can find another job. Meatpacking companies therefore face a choice: raise wages or find other workers.
Hardly coincidentally, unionization of packinghouse workers has fallen, too -- from more than 80 percent in 1980 to less than 50 percent today. In Nebraska, like other meatpacking states, right-to-work laws prohibit unions from requiring membership. Nebraska’s average manufacturing wage is $12.32 an hour, 13 percent below the production average for the other 15 states where meatpacking is a major industry. Immigration raids didn’t lead to increased wages any more than they created jobs. If anything, they lowered them by making workers more vulnerable, creating a climate of fear in which union organizing was much harder.
Sanctions enforcement, however, did become a means to pressure Congress and advance a political agenda for guest-worker reform. (Guest workers are individuals recruited outside the United States by employers who bring them in under temporary-contract visas.) One of Operation Vanguard’s architects, Mark Reed, boasted that he would force employer groups to support guest-worker legislation. “We depend on foreign labor,” he said. “If we don’t have illegal immigration anymore, we’ll have the political support for guest worker [reform].” Reed might have been a little ahead of his time, but he did get industry thinking. In the operation’s wake, large employer groups, the American Meat Institute prominent among them, began pushing for guest-worker programs tailored to industry.
Many U.S. industries are dependent on immigrant labor. The Pew Hispanic Center estimates that in 2001, undocumented workers constituted 58 percent of the workforce in agriculture, 23.8 percent in private household services, 16.6 percent in business services, 9.1 percent in restaurants, and 6.4 percent in construction.
In 2002 the AMI issued a call for immigration reform. It suggested automating the INS database so employers could verify immigration documents easily and moderating enforcement actions against employers who try to comply. The centerpiece: “creating a new, separate employment-based immigrant visa category covering mid- to low-skill workers.” The proposal has been embraced by the Essential Worker Immigration Coalition (EWIC), which encompasses 40 employer groups from drugstores (think Wal-Mart) to hotel chains.
President Bush, who signed on to this general approach at the beginning of his administration, calls it “connecting willing employers with willing employees.” For industry, the adoption of guest-worker proposals by the president and powerful forces in Congress is an indirect benefit from Operation Vanguard and the Nebraska Beef raid. These enforcement actions helped provide the political momentum for guest-worker proposals.
Meanwhile, two major bills reflect the AMI and EWIC agenda. One, authored by Senators Ted Kennedy and John McCain, would allow corporations to recruit 400,000 workers annually, offering the chance for permanent residency if they remain constantly employed for four years. The currently undocumented could become guest workers, too, with possible legal residence after six years. At the same time, employer sanctions would be enforced much more systematically, forcing workers to either sign up or leave. Another bill, by Senators John Cornyn and Jon Kyl, would allow companies to recruit guest workers for more limited periods, after which they’d have to go home. The currently undocumented would have to go back home, too, in order to apply for guest-worker visas. The bill has no real legalization program, and would direct enormous new resources into sanctions enforcement.
The AMI doesn’t endorse any proposal. According to Rob Rosado, director of legislative affairs, meatpackers would like to normalize the status of the industry’s current workforce “to allow the people already working to continue to work.” The key issue, however, is the constant stream of new workers needed to keep plants running. “We support a new guest-worker visa,” Rosado explains, “since there isn’t one currently for permanent, full-time, nonseasonal workers.” Asked if the industry would accept a basic wage guarantee for those workers, he responded, “We don’t want the government setting wages. The market determines wages.”
If either bill becomes law, plants like Nebraska Beef could gradually recruit new guest workers as normal turnover opened jobs, essentially doing legally what the government accused the company of doing in violation of the law five years ago.
Immigrants will only have rights if they can fight for them, says Tiberio Chavez, who helped lead successful efforts to organize Northern States Beef. Proposals for immigration reform can make that easier or harder. “The companies want to make money, and if one day they can make us work without pay, then they will. But the day we organize a strong united effort we will force them to grant us the rights we are entitled to, because all human beings have rights,” he exclaims.
But union organizers believe that under Congress’ guest-worker reform proposals, they’d have a hard time assisting employees who couldn’t get a green card and didn’t want to register as guest workers. Social Security and Department of Labor inspectors would check the immigration status of any worker who complained about unpaid wages or overtime, and under this new regime of employer sanctions, the undocumented would be more vulnerable than ever. Workers on temporary visas would be unlikely to sign a union card the next time the line speed got too fast, or if wages fell even further behind the manufacturing average.
Sergio Sosa was the key organizer in the union-organizing alliance between Omaha Together One Community, a community project of the Industrial Areas Foundation, and the United Food and Commercial Workers. He says the obstacles for guest workers would be daunting. “With community support it’s still possible for workers to resist, even when they have no papers,” Sosa says, pointing to the way the documented and undocumented worked together at Northern States Beef. “But guest workers are cut off from the community. By definition they’re temporary, and can’t put down roots or look to a future here. Their function is to work and leave.”
Last year Rodolfo Bobadilla, bishop of Huehuetenango, Guatemala, visited his countrymen working in Omaha’s meatpacking plants. With the clarity of an outsider, he observed that “the U.S. needs these workers, so there should be a system to allow them to come to this country in a legal manner.” But when only men come and only temporarily, he warned, “the family disintegrates. Our people here need to keep their own culture, participate in social movements, and integrate themselves in U.S. culture. People must plant their roots.”
In Congress, African American political leaders agree. Members of the Congressional Black Caucus have sponsored a third alternative, the comprehensive immigration-reform proposal by Representative Sheila Jackson Lee. Her bill, like that signed by Ronald Reagan in 1986, would allow the undocumented to apply for permanent legal status if they have lived here for five years and understand basic English. Fees paid by applicants would fund job training and creation in communities with high unemployment. The bill has no guest-worker provision, and instead strengthens enforcement of immigrants’ workplace rights.
“This would be better for us,” says Sosa. “If we’re going to improve conditions in our communities, we need legal status for those who lack it. We’re prepared to struggle for something better, but we need enforcement which will make that easier, not harder.”
This April, fully four years after the effort to unionize Nebraska Beef’s immigrant workers went down to defeat, the National Labor Relations Board in Washington threw out the election results, citing the company’s illegal intimidation tactics. The union and its backers scheduled a new election -- but soon withdrew their petition in light of renewed intimidation efforts. Jesus Lopez, a former employee who was fired in April, said management was even threatening to close the plant if the union won.
“It took four years to throw out that old election because of the fear those same tactics created,” Sosa exclaims angrily. “It’s pretty obvious to workers that the company can violate all kinds of laws without paying a penalty. And Congress, instead of enforcing the laws that should guarantee workers their rights and allow them to raise the incomes of their families, is debating an immigration reform that will just help the company even more. Who is the real winner here?”
David Bacon writes about labor and immigration. His book, The Children of NAFTA, was published last year by the University of California Press, and his photodocumentary on transnational communities, Beyond Borders, is due out next year.
That’s all folks!
Colin